Geographic concentration of employment discussion

User Generated

kvatlhaznb1997

Programming

Description

Read the PDF and write a 1.5 page single space report.

Unformatted Attachment Preview

Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Public Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jpube Do local energy prices and regulation affect the geographic concentration of employment?☆ Matthew E. Kahn a, b,⁎, Erin T. Mansur b, c a b c UCLA Institute of the Environment, La Kretz Hall, Suite 300, 619 Charles E. Young Drive East, Box 951496, Los Angeles, CA 90095, United States National Bureau of Economic Research, United States Dartmouth College, Department of Economics, 6106 Rockefeller Hall, Hanover, NH 03755, United States a r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 9 September 2011 Received in revised form 18 January 2013 Accepted 11 March 2013 Available online 16 March 2013 Keywords: Manufacturing employment Electricity prices Regulation a b s t r a c t Manufacturing industries differ with respect to their energy intensity, labor-to-capital ratio and their pollution intensity. Across the United States, there is significant variation in electricity prices and labor and environmental regulation. This paper examines whether the basic logic of comparative advantage can explain the geographical clustering of U.S. manufacturing. We document that energy-intensive industries concentrate in low electricity price counties and labor-intensive industries avoid pro-union counties. We find mixed evidence that pollution-intensive industries locate in counties featuring relatively lax Clean Air Act regulation. © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Between 1998 and 2009, aggregate U.S. manufacturing jobs declined by 35 percent while the total production of this industry grew by 21 percent. 1 This loss of manufacturing jobs has important implications for the quality of life of the middle class. Manufacturing offers less educated workers employment in relatively well paying jobs (Neal, 1995). Despite public concerns about the international outsourcing of jobs, over eleven million people continue to work in the U.S. manufacturing sector. 2 The ability of local areas to attract and retain such manufacturing jobs continues to play an important ☆ We thank Severin Borenstein, Joseph Cullen, Lucas Davis, Meredith Fowlie, Jun Ishii, Enrico Moretti, Nina Pavcnik, Frank Wolak, Catherine Wolfram, and the seminar participants at the 2009 UCEI Summer Camp, UBC Environmental Economics and Climate Change Workshop 2010, the 2012 UC Berkeley Power Conference, ClaremontMcKenna College, Amherst College, the University of Alberta, the University of Michigan, and Yale University for their useful comments. We thank Wayne Gray for sharing data with us and Koichiro Ito and William Bishop for assisting with Fig. 1. We thank the two anonymous reviewers for their several useful comments. ⁎ Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: mkahn@ioe.ucla.edu (M.E. Kahn), erin.mansur@dartmouth.edu (E.T. Mansur). 1 The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics reports employment by sector. From 1998 to 2009, manufacturing employment fell from 17.6 million to 11.5 million (http://data.bls.gov/ timeseries/CES3000000001?data_tool=XGtable). The United Nations Statistics division reports gross value added by kind of economic activity at constant (2005) US dollars. From 1998 to 2009, manufacturing value went from $1348 billion to $1626 billion (http://data. un.org/Data.aspx?d=SNAAMA&f=grID%3a202%3bcurrID%3aUSD%3bpcFlag%3a0%3bitID% 3a12). 2 In March, 2011, 11.67 million people worked in manufacturing (NAICS 31–33) (source: http://www.bls.gov/iag/tgs/iag31-33.htm). 0047-2727/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.03.002 role in determining the vibrancy of their local economy (Greenstone et al., 2010). Ongoing research examines the role that government regulations and local factor prices play in attracting or deflecting manufacturing employment. During a time when unemployment rates differ greatly across states, there remains an open question concerning the role that regulation plays in determining the geography of productive activity. A leading example of this research is Holmes' (1998) study that exploited sharp changes in labor regulation at adjacent state boundaries. He posited that counties that are located in Right-toWork states have a more “pro-business” environment than their nearby neighboring county located in a pro-union state. He used this border-pairs approach to establish that between 1952 and 1988 there has been an increasing concentration of manufacturing activity on the Right-to-Work side of the border. A recent Wall Street Journal piece claimed that, between the years 2000 and 2008, 4.8 million Americans moved from union states to Right-to-Work states. 3 In this paper, we build on Holmes' core research methodology along three dimensions. First, we focus on the modern period from 1998 to 2009. During this time period, the manufacturing sector experienced significant job destruction as intense international competition has taken place (Davis et al., 2006; Bernard et al., 2006). This time period covers the start of the recent deep downturn in the national economy and the earlier 2000 to 2001 recession. Past research has documented that industrial concentration is affected by energy prices 3 Arthur B. Laffer and Stephen Moore. “Boeing and the Union Berlin Wall.” http://online. wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703730804576317140858893466.html. 106 M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 (Carlton, 1983), environmental regulation (Becker and Henderson, 2000; Greenstone, 2002; Walker, 2012), and labor regulation and general state level pro-business policies (Holmes, 1998; Chirinko and Wilson, 2008). Second, we use the border-pair methodology to study the relative importance of these three key determinants of the geographic concentration of manufacturing jobs in one unified framework. Third, we examine the heterogeneity of industries' response to these policies. We estimate a reduced form econometric model of equilibrium employment variation across counties that allow us to study how energy regulation, labor regulation and environmental regulation are associated with the spatial distribution of employment while holding constant the other policies of interest. Our identification strategy exploits within border-pair variation in energy prices and regulation to tease out the role that each of these factors play in influencing the geographical patterns of manufacturing employment. As we discuss below, county border pairs share many common attributes including local labor market conditions, spatial amenities, and proximity to markets. We compare our estimates of policy effects in regression results with different levels of geographic controls to see how robust our results are across different specifications. This paper studies where different industries cluster across different types of counties as a function of county regulation status. In the case of manufacturing, we disaggregate manufacturing into 21 three-digit NAICS industries. These industries differ along three dimensions; the industry's energy consumption per unit of output, the industry's labor-to-capital ratio, and the industry's pollution intensity. We model each county as embodying three key bundled attributes; its utility's average industrial electricity price, its state's labor regulation, and the county's Clean Air Act regulatory status. The basic logic of comparative advantage yields several testable hypotheses. In a similar spirit as Ellison and Glaeser (1999), we test for the role of geographical “natural advantages” by studying the sorting patterns of diverse industries. Energy-intensive industries should avoid high electricity price counties.4 Labor-intensive manufacturing should avoid pro-union counties. Pollution-intensive industries should avoid counties that face strict Clean Air Act regulation. We use a countyindustry level panel data set covering the years 1998 to 2009 to test all three of these claims. The paper also examines the relationship between energy prices and employment for specific industries. We recognize that manufacturing is just one sector of the economy and thus we examine how other major non-manufacturing industries are affected by energy, labor and environmental regulation. For 21 manufacturing industries and 15 major non-manufacturing industries, we estimate this relationship. We find that energy prices are not an important correlate of geographical concentration for most non-manufacturing industries. However, employment in expanding industries such as Credit Intermediation (NAICS 522), Professional, Scientific and Technical Services (NAICS 541), and Management of Companies and Enterprises (NAICS 551) is responsive to electricity prices with implied elasticities of approximately −.15. In comparison, the most electricity-intensive manufacturing industry, primary metals, has an elasticity of −1.17. 2. Empirical framework Our empirical work will focus on examining the correlates of the geographic clusters of employment and establishments by industry starting in 1998. Building on Holmes' (1998) approach, we rely heavily on estimating statistical models that include border-pair fixed effects. A border pair will consist of two adjacent counties. 4 Energy-intensive industries will also attempt to avoid high oil, coal, and natural gas prices, as well. However, our identification strategy examines differences between neighboring counties and while there are regional differences in coal and natural gas, these differences are likely to be small between neighboring counties. Comparing the geographic concentration of employment within a border pair controls for many relevant cost factors. Manufacturing firms face several tradeoffs in choosing where to locate, how much to produce, and which inputs to use. To reduce their cost of production, they would like to locate in areas featuring cheap land, low quality-adjusted wages, lax regulatory requirements and cheap energy. They would also like to be close to final consumers and input suppliers in order to conserve on transportation costs. Within a border pair, we posit that local wages are roughly constant as are location specific amenities and proximity to input suppliers and final consumers. Our unit of analysis will be a county/industry/year. First we study the geographic concentration of 21 manufacturing industries using the U.S. County Business Patterns (CBP) data over the years 1998 to 2009. 5 The CBP reports for each county and year the employment count, establishment count and establishment count by employment size. This last set of variables is important because the CBP suppresses the actual employment count and reports a “0” for many observations (Isserman and Westervelt, 2006). 6 Throughout this paper, we assume that each industry differs with respect to its production process (and hence in their firms' response to electricity prices and regulation) but any two firms within the same industry have the same production function. In general, energy inputs and the firm's environmental control technology may be either substitutes or complements with labor in a given industry (Berman and Bui, 2001). Our paper studies the effects of regulations on overall employment, combining both these substitution effects as well as scale effects. Our main econometric model is presented in Eq. (1). Estimates of Eq. (1) generate new finding about the equilibrium statistical relationship between regulation, electricity prices and manufacturing location choices between 1998 and 2009. The unit of analysis is by county i, county-pair j, industry k, and year t. County i is located in utility u and state s. In most of the specifications we report below, we will focus on counties that are located in metropolitan areas. 7 elec empijuskt ¼ β 1 P elec ut þ β 2 P ut ⋅ElecIndexkt þ β 3 Right s ⋅LabCapRatiokt þβ 4 Nonattainit þ β 5 Nonattainit ⋅PollIndexk þ β 6 NoMonitori þβ 7 NoMonitori ⋅PollIndexk þ θ1 ElecIndexkt þ θ2 Right s þ θ3 LabCapRatiokt þθ4 PollIndexk þ f ðPollit Þ þ δZi þ α j þ γkt þ π st þ εijuskt : ð1Þ In this regression, the dependent variable will be a measure of county/industry/year employment. The first term on the right side of Eq. (1) presents the log of the average electricity prices that the industry faces in a specific county. The second term allows this price effect to vary with the industry's electricity-intensity index. In the regressions, the electricity-intensity index is normalized to range from 0 to 1 for ease in interpreting the results. 8 Third is an interaction term between whether state s has Right-to-Work laws (Right) and the 5 County Business Patterns (http://www.census.gov/econ/cbp/download/index.htm). We use 1998 as our start date because this was the first year in which NAICS rather than SIC codes where used. All data use the 2002 NAICS definitions. 6 The CBP suppress employment counts to protect firms' privacy in certain cases. In 35 percent of our observations, employment equals zero despite there being a positive count of establishments in that county, industry and year. To address this issue, we impute the employment data using the establishment count data when suppression occurs. The CBP provides the counts of establishments by firm size category. We take the midpoint of employment for each of these categories and use the county/industry/year establishment count data across the employment size categories (1–4, 5–9, 10–19, 20–49, 50–99, 100–249, 250–499, 500–999, 1000–1499, 1500–2499, 2500–4999 and 5000+) to impute the employment count for observations that are suppressed. We top code the 5000+ employment observations at 6000. 7 MSA counties account for most of the population (78% of the 1995 US population), manufacturing establishments (78% in sample), and manufacturing workforce (74% in sample). 8 The NBER productivity data report electricity intensity in electricity usage (in kWh) per dollar value of shipments. We normalize this measure to range from zero to one to simplify the interpretation of the price coefficients. M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 industry's labor-to-capital ratio (LabCapRatio). Finally, we examine the effect of environmental policy. This includes the interaction of an indicator of nonattainment status (Nonattainment) and a continuous index of pollution from an industry (PollIndex). We also examine the interaction effect of an indicator of whether a county does not monitor the pollutant of interest (NoMonitor) and the PollIndex variable. In estimating these policy-relevant variables, we try to control for potentially confounding factors. There are several variables that we would estimate in a traditional difference-in-differences model, including the direct effects of ElecIndex, Right, LabCapRatio, and PollIndex: θ1 − θ4. However, all of these are perfectly collinear with the various fixed effects that we estimate. For example, the direct effect of Right-to-Work states cannot be separately identified given the inclusion of state-year fixed effects. We do control for a flexible function of pollution concentration levels, pollit.9 The Z vector has county variables: a county's population in 1970, its distance to the nearest metropolitan area's Central Business District (CBD), the county's land area, and the log of the 1990 housing values.10 In the core specifications we control for a county-pair fixed effect, industry-year fixed effects and state-year fixed effects. We rely heavily on these border-pair fixed effects to soak up spatial variation in local labor market conditions, climate amenities, and proximity to intermediate input providers and final customers. Past studies such as Dumais et al. (2002) have emphasized the importance of labor pooling as an explanation for why firms in the same industry locate close together. The industry-year fixed effects control for any macro level changes in demand due to shifting national consumption trends or world trade. 11 The state–year fixed effects control for local labor market conditions such as local wage trends and any state policy that affects a firm's propensity to locate within a state. For example, some states such as Missouri have low taxes while others such as California do not.12 We use several different dependent variables. We begin by examining the number of manufacturing employees. We also present results that focus on an industry's percentage of total county employment. In another specification, we report results for the natural log of employment, which is estimated only for observations with positive employment. As discussed below, 14 percent of our observations have no establishments and thus no employees. For each manufacturing industry, we can measure the electricity intensity and the labor–capital ratio. These data are from NBER Productivity Data Base and cover 1997 to 2009. 13 Below, we will also 9 Counties are more likely to be assigned to nonattainment status if their ambient air pollution levels in the recent past have been higher. If booming counties have high regulation levels, then a researcher could conclude that regulation raises employment levels when in fact reverse causality is generating this relationship. To sidestep this problem, we include a flexible function of the county's ambient pollution level. 10 Adjacent counties are unlikely to be “twins.” The classic monocentric model of urban economics predicts that counties closer to a major Central Business District will feature higher population densities and higher land prices than more suburban counties. We have also estimated specifications that included other county attributes such as a dummy indicating whether the county is the metropolitan area's center county and another dummy that indicates whether the county is adjacent to an Ocean or a Great Lake. The results are robust to controlling for these variables and are available on request. In Appendix Table A1, we present formal tests of whether our explanatory variables included in the Z vector are “balanced.” We find that these covariates vary by treatment for high electricity prices, labor regulation, and environmental regulation. In a regression reported in Table 5, we include linear trends for each covariate to test whether our results are robust. 11 Linn (2009) documents that linkages between manufacturing industries amplify the effect of macro energy price shocks. Given that energy-intensive industries are important input suppliers to other industries, there could be industry–year effects driven by such linkages. Including the industry–year fixed effects helps to address this issue. For more on the macroeconomics impacts of energy price changes see Killian (2008). 12 Recent empirical work has documented that minimum wage differences across states do not influence the locational choices of low skill jobs (Dube et al., 2010). 13 See http://www.nber.org/data/nbprod2005.html. We thank Wayne Gray for providing us with data that extends the sample through 2009. 107 present results for non-manufacturing industries but we cannot measure their electricity, labor, or pollution intensity. As such, our main results focus on manufacturing where we can test for the role of geographic regulations in attracting employment activity. The interaction terms presented in Eq. (1) allow us to test three hypotheses. The first hypothesis is that energy-intensive industries cluster on the low electricity price side of the border. The second hypothesis is that labor-intensive industries cluster on the Right-to-Work Side of the border. The third hypothesis is that high emission industries cluster in the low environmental regulation side of the border. We estimate Eq. (1) using weighted least squares. We will also present results in which we instrument for local electricity prices to test whether these prices are driven by exogenous factors. Note that each county/industry/year observation enters multiple times since a county can be adjacent to several counties. We place equal weight on each county/industry/year observation with weights based on a county's number of borders. 14 Multiple entries also require standard error corrections: we need to cluster at this level or one that is more aggregated. We cluster by major utility to allow for serial correlation and spatial correlation. In a second set of econometric results, we employ a more conventional model without border pairs. We include county fixed effects and exploit within county variation in environmental regulation and electricity prices to estimate the association between these variables and employment clusters. In Eq. (2), the unit of analysis is by county i, industry k, electric utility u, and year t. We estimate Eq. (2) with county, industry–year, and state–year, fixed effects: elec empiuskt ¼ β1 P elec ut þ β 2 P ut ⋅ElecIndexkt þ β 3 Right s ⋅LabCapRatiokt þβ4 Nonattainit þ β5 Nonattainit ⋅PollIndexk þ β6 NoMonitor i þβ7 NoMonitor i ⋅PollIndexk þ f ðPollit Þ þ α i þ γ kt þ πst þ εiuskt : ð2Þ By exploiting within-county variation over time in electricity prices and environmental regulation, these estimates can be thought of as a short-term response to changes in the relevant explanatory variables. The county fixed effects regression presented in Eq. (2) also addresses the criticism that there are fixed county attributes that are not captured by our controls that could be correlated with the key explanatory variables. If these unobservables are time invariant, then including county fixed effects address this concern. 3. Three margins affecting geographic concentration of employment A key identifying assumption in this paper is that there exists within county border pair variation in labor regulation intensity, electricity prices, and Clean Air Act intensity that allows us to observe “exogenous” variation. 3.1. Electricity prices Electricity prices vary across electric utility jurisdictions (see Fig. 1 for county average prices in 1998). Adjacent counties can lie within different electric utility jurisdictions. Each of the approximately 460 U.S. electric utilities charges different electricity prices. In the ideal research design that relies on county-level employment data, each county would be served by one utility. In this case, we would have a sharp spatial regression discontinuity at each county border but this is not the case. Some major counties have multiple utilities. While other utilities span several counties. If two adjacent counties lie within 14 The analytic weights are the inverse of the number of times a given county/industry/ year enters the sample. 108 M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 Fig. 1. Industrial electricity prices in 1998 ($/kWh). the same electric utility district, then there will be no within border pair variation for these counties. 15 Most of our border pairs are within the same utility area. However, for those pairs that cross utilities, the price differences can be significant. The median price differential is about one cent for border pair counties that lie in different utility areas. For five percent of these counties, the difference is over nine cents a kWh. For firms in electricity-intensive industries, this differential represents about seven percent of revenue. This fact highlights that there are significant cost savings for a subset of industries for choosing to locate in the lower electricity price county within a county-pair. Most U.S. retail electricity prices are determined through rate hearings where regulated firms can recover rates through average cost pricing. During the early part of our sample, most rates were the function of past costs that had little to do with current production costs.16 In regions that restructured their wholesale electricity markets, retail rates were frozen for an initial period when utilities were to recover “stranded” assets. Today, the retail prices in these markets reflect wholesale costs, as passed on to consumers through retail competition. Our electricity price data are constructed from data available from the Energy Information Administration (EIA) form 861.17 We determine prices by aggregating revenue from industrial customers at any utility that serves these customers in a given county and year. We divide this industrial revenue by the quantity of electricity sold to industrial customers by those utilities in that year.18 For clustering, we assign the county to one of the 178 major utilities in our sample. 19 3.2. Labor regulation We follow Holmes (1998) and assign each county to whether it is located in a Right-to-Work state or not. Today, there are 22 states that are Right-to-Work states. A Right-to-Work law secures the right of employees to decide for themselves whether or not to join or financially support a union. The set of states includes Alabama, Arizona, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Idaho, Iowa, Kansas, Louisiana, Mississippi, Nebraska, Nevada, North Carolina, North Dakota, Oklahoma, South Carolina, South Dakota, Tennessee, Texas, Utah, Virginia and Wyoming.20 When we restrict our sample to the set of counties that are both in a metropolitan area, we have relatively few cases in which one county 17 See http://www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/electricity/page/eia861.html. In fact, industrial customers face a non-linear structure that has a per day fixed meter charge, an energy charge per kWh consumed, and an additional demand charge based on peak hourly consumption (kW) during a billing period. In addition, rates may differ by firm size and type. Some large firms face tariffs with a specific tariff that applies to them. Our empirical strategy imposes that firms respond to cross county average price variation when in fact firms will recognize that they face a non-linear pricing schedule. 19 For counties with multiple utilities, the major utility is defined as the utility with the largest total sales across all of its industrial customers. 20 Recently, this policy has been debated in states including New Hampshire, Missouri and Indiana. In December 2012, Michigan passed right-to-work legislation. 18 15 Davis et al. (2008) find that, in 2000, about 60 percent of the variation in electricity prices paid by manufacturing plants can be explained by county fixed effects. The remaining differences may be due to multiple utilities serving a county, non-linear pricing where customers are charged both a usage fee and a peak consumption fee, or because of different rates negotiated with the utilities. Davis et al. find evidence of scale economies in delivery that are consistent with observed quantity discounts. 16 High capital costs of nuclear plants and Public Utility Regulatory Policy Act (PURPA) contracts from the 1970s and 1980s led to substantial regional variation in retail electricity prices during the 1990s. See Joskow (1989, 2006) for a discussion of retail pricing in the electricity industry. M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 lies in a Right-to-Work state and the other county lies in a non-Rightto-Work State. Two examples of such a “hybrid” metropolitan areas are Kansas City, Missouri and Washington D.C. Below, we also report results in which we use all U.S. counties. 21 3.3. Environmental regulation The Clean Air Act assigns counties to low regulation (Attainment Status) and high regulation (Nonattainment Status) based on past ambient air pollution readings. The Environmental Protection Agency does not monitor air quality in every county. Another indicator of low regulation is if ambient air pollution is not monitored. Kahn (1997) documents higher manufacturing growth rates in counties that do not monitor ambient pollution relative to those that do monitor. Within county border-pairs, there is variation in environmental regulation both due to cross-sectional differences (i.e., high regulated counties that are adjacent to less regulated cleaner counties) and due to changes over time (reclassification of counties from attainment to nonattainment and vice-versa). In this paper, we focus on ozone as one of the six criteria pollutants. We also estimate similar models for carbon monoxide and particulate matter. 22 We use a continuous measure of ozone pollution intensity. 23 We divide total emissions by the annual value added of each industry (from the NBER productivity data) to construct a pollution intensity index. Finally, we normalize the index to range from zero to one for ease in interpreting coefficients. We hypothesize that high-polluting industries—including petroleum and coal products, nonmetallic mineral products, and paper manufacturing—should be the most responsive to avoiding the nonattainment sides of the county border pair and in locating in that county within the county border pair that does not monitor ambient ozone. The data indicating a county's Clean Air Act regulatory status are from the EPA's Greenbook.24 Our county/ year ambient air pollution data are from the U.S. EPA AIRS data base. Our regressions include a cubic function of a county's ambient ozone level. 4. Results Table 1 reports the summary statistics. The uneven distribution of manufacturing activity is revealed in the first row. The average county/ industry/year observation has 668 jobs but the median is 111 and the maximum is 158,573. It is relevant to note that these summary statistics are based on all counties located in metropolitan areas and excludes about 75 percent of U.S. counties. Of this sample, 86 percent have at least one employee in that county, industry, and year. Table 2 reports the names and key statistics for the 21 manufacturing industries that we study. The rows are sorted from the most energy-intensive industry (Primary Metals) to the least energyintensive industry (Computer and Electronic Product Manufacturing). The most energy-intensive industry uses sixteen times as much electricity per unit of output as the least electricity-intensive industry. In Table 2, we report each industry's labor-to-capital ratio. Apparel, Leather, Textiles, and Furniture are some of the most labor-intensive industries. In contrast, the primary metals industry has a tiny laborto-capital ratio. The cross-industry correlation between the electricity 21 In metropolitan areas, there are 36 counties that make up 28 different pairs where a state line is crossed. For the full sample, 425 counties abut a state line and make 443 county pairs. 22 We estimate Eq. (1) using two other measures of local environmental regulation intensity: a county's carbon monoxide (CO) nonattainment status; and a county's particulate matter (PM) nonattainment status. 23 From EPA's NEI data, we aggregate total tons of emissions by industry, year and pollutant (see ftp://ftp.epa.gov/EmisInventory/2002finalnei/2002_final_v3_2007_ summaries/point/allneicap_annual_11302007.zip). For ozone, we aggregate tons of nitrogen oxides and tons of volatile organic compounds. 24 http://epa.gov/airquality/greenbk/. 109 index and the labor-to-capital ratio equals − 0.4. In the right column of Table 2, we report each of these industries' pollution intensity. Pollution intensity is positively correlated with the electricity index (0.5) and negatively correlated with the labor-to-capital ratio (− 0.4). In Table 3, we report our first estimates of Eq. (1). Recall that each county pair consists of two metropolitan area counties that are physically adjacent. Controlling for county-pair fixed effects, industry– year fixed effects, and state–year fixed effects, and a vector of county attributes (log of land area, log of the distance to the closest metro area's Central Business District, the log of the county's 1970 population, and the log of the 1990 housing values), we focus on the role of electricity prices and labor and environmental regulation in determining the geographic location of manufacturing clusters. 25 As shown in column (1), we find evidence of a negative relationship between electricity prices and manufacturing employment activity for all manufacturing industries whose normalized electricity index is greater than 0.094. 26 We find the largest negative effects of electricity prices on the most electricity-intensive industry, primary metals, has an implied price elasticity of employment of − 1.65. 27 To better understand the magnitude of these effects, assume that a state implemented a carbon price of $15 per ton of CO2. Given the carbon intensity of producing power in different regions of the US, this can be mapped into a change in electricity prices (see Kahn and Mansur, 2010). Because of the variation in carbon-intensive electricity markets and energy-intensive manufacturing across states, our coefficients imply that the employment losses could be much larger in places like Ohio (21,884 jobs or 3.8 percent) than in California (4648, or − 0.3 percent). 28 Controlling for electricity prices, we find that labor-intensive manufacturing clusters on the Right-to-Work side of the county border pair. For the most labor-intensive industry (Apparel), the coefficients imply 443 more jobs on the right-to-work side of the border, relative to an extremely capital-intensive industry like petroleum. This is approximately half of the average number of workers in a given county/industry/year. It is relevant to contrast this finding with Holmes' (1998) work. He finds that the share of total employment that is in manufacturing is greater by about one third in Rightto-Work states. He did not disaggregate manufacturing into distinct industries. If the Right-to-Work status simply reflected this overall ideology then we might not observe that labor-intensive industries are more likely to cluster there. Our finding of a positive industryaverage labor intensity interaction with the state's labor policies highlights the importance of allowing for industry disaggregation and is consistent with economic intuition. Controlling for electricity prices and labor regulation, we also study the role of environmental regulation. As expected, we find that employment in high-pollution industries is lower in high-regulation (nonattainment) counties. We also find that employment is higher for high-ozone industries in counties that do not monitor ozone. 25 For the first column, when we look at the level of manufacturing employment, we use the level of population in 1970 to be consistent. The results are similar when log historic population is used instead. Recognizing that within a county, such as Los Angeles County, firms may seek out the cheapest utility within the county, we have re-estimated our models using the minimum price in the county and find very similar results. 26 Deschenes (2012) uses a state/year panel approach using a longer time series than we do and does not disaggregate manufacturing industries beyond; “durables” and “non-durables.” Controlling for state and year fixed effects, for “non-durables” he reports a positive correlation of electricity prices and employment based on a specification with state and year fixed effects. 27 This is the sum of the coefficient on price and the coefficient on price interacted with the index (which is normalized to range from 0 to 1, where 1 is the most electricity-intensive industry (primary metals)) all divided by the average employment in our sample: (114.6 + (−1217.6)*1)/668 = −1.65. 28 See Kahn and Mansur (2010) for a discussion of the assumptions regarding this application. 110 M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 Table 1 Summary statistics. 1st Variable Units Obs Mean Mnfct. employees % Total emp. ln(Employment) Any manufacturing Suppressed data Electricity price Electricity index Right to work laws Labor/capital ratio Ozone emis. rate Ozone nonattainment PM Nonattainment CO nonattainment Workers % 157,459 157,459 135,531 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 157,459 668 0.7% 4.97 0.86 0.43 $0.065 0.33 0.44 0.018 1.79 0.34 0.11 0.04 0/1 0/1 $/kWh kWh/shipments 0/1 Work hours/capital Tons/$MM value added 0/1 0/1 0/1 Std. dev. 2373 1.8% 2.05 0.35 0.50 $0.024 0.23 0.50 0.013 2.55 0.47 0.32 0.19 Min 0 0.0% 0.00 0.00 0.00 $0.000 0.00 0.00 0.001 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00 3rd Quartile Median Quartile 10 0.0% 3.54 1.00 0.00 $0.050 0.16 0.00 0.008 0.34 0.00 0.00 0.00 111 0.2% 5.19 1.00 0.00 $0.057 0.22 0.00 0.015 0.63 0.00 0.00 0.00 515 0.7% 6.48 1.00 1.00 $0.069 0.44 1.00 0.024 1.90 1.00 0.00 0.00 Max 158,573 56.4% 11.97 1.00 1.00 $0.523 1.00 1.00 0.076 9.71 1.00 1.00 1.00 Notes: An observation is by county, year, and 3-digit NAICS industry code. Index is normalized to range from zero to one. A distinctive feature of our study is that we simultaneously study the marginal effects of energy prices, labor regulation, and environmental regulation in one unified framework. In Table 3's columns (2–4), we present our estimates for what we would find if we studied these variables individually. In column (2), we find that the electricity price interaction grows more negative by 16% and the labor intensity interaction shrinks by roughly 33% and the environmental regulation interaction grows more negative by roughly 19%. The results in column (5) of Table 3 switch the dependent variable to the ratio of a county/year's jobs in a given industry divided by total county employment. This was Holmes' (1998) dependent variable. This measure better captures the composition of jobs within a county. The electricity price and labor regulation results are similar to the results in column (1) but in this specification we reject the hypothesis that environmental regulation is a statistically significant determinant of where manufacturing clusters. For the primary metals industry, we find that a ten percent increase in electricity prices is associated with a 0.034 percentage point reduction in the share of workers in the county who works in this industry. In Table 3's column (6), we use the log of the county/industry/ year's employment and thus lose the observations for which there are zero jobs. The electricity price and labor policy results are qualitatively quite similar to those reported in Eq. (1). Based on this specification, we estimate an employment electricity price elasticity of − 0.91 for the primary metals industry. Overall, we conclude that our environmental regulation results are sensitive to functional form assumptions. Following Holmes (1998), the last column of Table 3 includes just small counties. Namely, the sample consists of paired counties whose centroids are within 30 miles of each other. Small counties are more likely to have similar unobserved shocks. Of course, smaller counties are likely to be in more densely populated areas as well, so we are exploring a different subset of the population. We find that the main results are qualitatively robust, with similar signs and significance, as our main findings. However, the policy effects are attenuated suggesting that there is heterogeneity in the employment effects between large and small counties. Appendix Table A2 explores how our results change across a range of centroid distances. Given the estimates in column (1) of Table 3, we can now compare the relative sensitivities of a given industry to energy prices, labor policy, and environmental policies. For an industry like petroleum— which is energy intensive, capital intensive, and a high-ozone polluter—banning Right-to-Work laws would have the same effect on employment as an eight percent increase in electricity prices. In contrast, if a petroleum manufacturer's county falls into nonattainment with environmental regulations, this is akin to tripling electricity prices. Other industries that are not energy or pollution intensive are not as negatively affected by either higher energy prices or pollution regulation. For example, for apparel manufacturing, repealing a right-to-work law is akin to a fourfold increase in electricity prices. In Table 4, we modify Eq. (1) by estimating separate coefficients on electricity prices for each manufacturing industry. In other words, we relax the index restriction on electricity prices that was imposed on the results reported in Table 3. We also estimate Eq. (1) separately for fifteen major non-manufacturing industries. 29 The results reported in Table 4 focus on the role of energy prices. We do not include labor or environmental regulations in these regressions. We report results for three dependent variables: the employment level, the industry's share of county employment and log employment. For ten manufacturing industries, we find negatively statistically significant correlations (at the five percent level) for the level of employment and electricity prices. For log employment, we find a negative correlation for seven of the industries. In the case of the share regressions, we find fewer negative correlations and actually find positive correlations for industries such as Textile Products (NAICS 314), Computers (NAICS 334) and Miscellaneous (NAICS 339). These two industries each have a very low energy intensity index. Finally, we note that Tables 3 and 4 imply similar employee-weighted average elasticities across industries for each specification. 30 The bottom panel of Table 4 reports similar regressions for nonmanufacturing industries. Many of these industries employ millions of people and have experienced sharp employment growth between 1998 and 2009. Employment in expanding industries such as Credit Intermediation (NAICS 522), Professional, Scientific and Technical Services (NAICS 541), and Management of Companies and Enterprises (NAICS 551) is responsive to electricity prices with elasticities of approximately − .15. However, for most non-manufacturing industries, we find that energy prices are not an important correlate of geographical concentration. An examination of BEA electricity cost shares indicates that there is not a cross-industry negative correlation between electricity prices and electricity cost shares for non-manufacturing industries.31 29 We choose the 15 industries with the most employees in 1998. Wholesale electronic markets (NAICS 425) had the ninth most jobs in 1998 but the NAICS 2002 reclassifications made it difficult to track this industry. Instead, we added the 16th most common job in 1998, Motor Vehicle and Parts Dealers (NAICS 441). Note that the border-pair and state–year fixed effects differ by non-manufacturing industry but are pooled for manufacturing industries. 30 For the linear specification, the implied elasticity is −.30 in Table 3 and −.41 in Table 4. For the log specification, they are .00 and −.10, respectively. Note that the log specification is conditional on any employment in the county/industry/year and therefore need not be the same as the linear model. 31 We use Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) input–output data to construct electricity cost shares. See http://www.bea.gov/industry/io_benchmark.htm. Using data for 2002, we define the cost share as the ratio of an industry's dollars spent on electric power (NAICS 2211) over its total industry output. M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 111 Table 2 Industry details. Electricity Normalized electricity Industry NAICS Index Index Labor-to-capital ratio Rate Primary metal manufacturing Paper manufacturing Textile mills Nonmetallic mineral product manufacturing Chemical manufacturing Plastics and rubber products manufacturing Wood product manufacturing Petroleum and coal products manufacturing Fabricated metal product manufacturing Printing and related support activities Textile product mills Food manufacturing Electrical equipment, appliance, and component manufacturing Furniture and related product manufacturing Leather and allied product manufacturing Machinery manufacturing Apparel manufacturing Miscellaneous manufacturing Beverage and tobacco product manufacturing Transportation equipment manufacturing Computer and electronic product manufacturing Correlation with electricity index Units 331 322 313 327 325 326 321 324 332 323 314 311 335 337 316 333 315 339 312 336 334 0.816 0.706 0.503 0.454 0.402 0.330 0.253 0.245 0.185 0.169 0.165 0.149 0.137 0.123 0.110 0.103 0.102 0.096 0.092 0.086 0.051 1.000 0.856 0.591 0.527 0.459 0.364 0.265 0.254 0.175 0.154 0.149 0.128 0.112 0.094 0.077 0.068 0.067 0.059 0.053 0.045 0.000 0.007 0.006 0.014 0.013 0.004 0.016 0.028 0.002 0.020 0.023 0.035 0.013 0.017 0.043 0.035 0.014 0.047 0.023 0.004 0.011 0.007 −0.395 Work hours/capital 2.845 5.007 1.222 7.046 1.897 0.974 3.294 9.715 0.426 0.632 0.345 0.749 0.336 1.376 0.547 0.156 0.028 0.204 0.422 0.401 0.038 0.485 Tons/$MM value added kWh/shipments 2002 Ozone emissions Notes: Industries are defined by three-digit NAICS codes. Data thanks to Wayne Gray. 4.1. Additional empirical tests In this section, we report additional regression results to test how our core results are affected by changing the sample, the sample years, including additional control variables and using different regulatory intensity measures. In Table 5's column (1), we report our results using all of the counties in the continental United States. Relative to the metro sample, the results for the full county sample yield the same coefficient signs but the absolute value of the coefficients for electricity prices and labor regulation shrinks by more than 50 percent. The coefficients on environmental regulation indicators shrink but by a much smaller percentage. In Table 5's column (2), we include linear time trends for each control variable such as population and home values to control for the possibility that counties differ with respect to their growth trajectory. The results are robust for controlling for these trends. Columns (3) and (4) use particulate matter and carbon monoxide pollution in place of the ozone for attainment status, monitoring status, high polluter industries, and concentration ratios. We find similar coefficients as in our main results but larger standard errors. 32 We recognize that there are cases in which a county's average electricity price could be correlated with the error term. A demand side explanation argues that a boom in local employment will result in an increase in the utility's demand. This requires more expensive power plants to operate, and electricity prices will increase. Second, industrial firms have some bargaining power in negotiating rates with the electric utility. Third, imprecise measurement of a firm's electricity price: measurement error leads to an attenuation bias of OLS estimates. To address these concerns, we present instrumental variable results in Table 5's column (5). We construct instruments using the product of the local utility's capacity shares of coal, oil and gas-fired power plants and the respective annual average fuel price.33 The sample size declines because we are missing fuel shares for some utilities. The 32 These results are not surprising given the few number of counties in nonattainment with these pollutants. 33 The shares data are from the EIA form 860 data for 1995. The fuel prices are from the EIA: coal prices are quantity-weighted annual averages from EIA form 423; oil prices are the spot WTI; and natural gas prices are the annual Henry Hub contract 1 prices. F-Statistic for the first stage equals 1139. The key finding to emerge in this instrumental variables case is that all industries (even those with the lowest energy intensity) now have a negative employment elasticity with respect to energy prices and the effect is much larger. The other coefficients on labor and environmental regulation are consistent with our core hypotheses. The recent deep recession has highlighted the importance of U.S. manufacturing to our economy. During a recession, few firms are creating jobs but industries and locations may differ with respect to the rate that they are shedding jobs. In Table 5's column (6), we re-estimate Eq. (1) using just two years of the data; 2008 and 2009 to see how our key explanatory variables affect employment during a major recession. The results are qualitatively similar to the full sample results reported in Table 3's column (1) but the negative effect of electricity prices on employment now holds for all industries. For the most electricity intensive industry, the implied elasticity is − 1.69. 34 An alternative strategy for studying the role of regulations and electricity prices on employment is to estimate Eq. (2) and include county fixed effects. In this case, the key interaction effects are identified from within county yearly variation in electricity prices, and the county's regulatory intensity and national changes in the industry's annual pollution intensity, labor intensity and electricity intensity. As shown in column (7), the results are remarkably similar to our results reported in Table 3's column (1) when we include border-pair fixed effects.35 4.2. Regulation's impact on industrial organization The County Business Patterns data provides information for each county/industry/year on its employment count and establishment 34 We have also estimated this regression using data from 2007 to 2009 and find quite similar results. 35 Incumbent firms are likely to face migration costs to relocate. If large capital costs are sunk, firms may delay relocating until their existing production facility depreciates or there are large differences in operating costs across geographic locations. One example is the Ocean Spray Corporation which plans to close its 250-worker cranberry concentrate processing plant in Bordentown, New Jersey in September 2013, and move it to Lehigh or Northampton counties in Pennsylvania. The closing facility is old and high cost. The company has claimed that it is attracted to the new Pennsylvania location because of lower power, water and trucking costs (http://www.philly.com/philly/blogs/ inq-phillydeals/South-Jersey-plant-to-close-250-jobs-moved-report.html). 112 M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 Table 3 Effect of regulation on manufacturing employment. ln Electricity price ln Price* electricity index Right to work* labor/capital Nonattainment county Nonattainment* pollution index No pollution monitor No monitor* pollution index R2 N Manufacturing employees (N) N N N Percent total employment ln N N (small counties) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 102.1** (51.2) −615.1** (245.1) −99.6** (43.8) 550.1*** (113.7) 0.36 1,120,243 0.17* (0.09) −0.51** (0.23) 8.63*** (3.28) −0.06** (0.03) 0.06 (0.09) 0.10*** (0.02) −0.18* (0.09) 0.13 958,946 0.25** (0.12) −1.16*** (0.33) 9.81*** (3.27) 0.02 (0.03) −0.09 (0.14) −0.04 (0.04) 0.20* (0.10) 0.53 947,301 107.6 (100.6) −570.3*** (193.2) 7939.2*** (2201.8) 41.0 (37.3) −200.1** (91.9) −32.8 (41.0) 359.3*** (89.2) 0.28 643,440 114.6 (180.3) −1217.6** (515.8) 9430.7*** (2851.9) 87.4* (46.1) −519.1*** (197.7) −99.9** (44.4) 542.8*** (110.3) 0.36 1,120,243 179.9 (193.5) −1410.1** (578.3) 6346.8*** (2346.8) 0.36 1,127,406 0.36 1,127,406 Notes: All regressions include cubic polynomials of ozone concentrations, county population in 1970, miles to CBD, area of county, 1990 housing values, and county–pair, industry– year, and state–year fixed effects. The omitted category is a county located in a pro-union state that does monitor air quality and is in attainment with Clean Air standards. Significance is noted at the 10% (*), 5% (**) and 1% (***) levels. Standard errors clustered by utility. count. In Table 6, we use these two pieces of information and in addition we calculate the average employment count per establishment. We report regression estimates of Eq. (1) using each of these as the dependent variable. Table 6's column (1) is identical to Table 3's column (1). In column (2), we report the establishment count regression. We find that the count of establishments responds to both Table 4 Employment regressions by industry. Employees in 1998 (1000s) Industry growth 311 312 313 314 315 316 321 322 323 324 325 326 327 331 332 333 334 335 336 337 339 1464 173 385 217 671 79 580 568 845 111 901 1030 508 615 1816 1444 1681 602 1911 604 737 −.004% −10% −51% −28% −68% −53% −1% −22% −24% −7% −11% −13% −5% −27% −14% −22% −37% −30% −15% −10% −7% 238 441 445 452 522 524 541 551 561 611 621 622 623 722 813 8926 1757 2944 4263 2688 2312 6052 2704 8366 2324 4482 5011 2511 7758 2488 26% 11% −1% −34% 22% 3% 33% 8% 27% 28% 27% 7% 19% 22% 12% NAICS BEA elect. cost share ln N Employees Manufacturing industries Coef. S.E. Coef. S.E. 1.17% 0.79% 2.40% 0.77% 0.54% 0.66% 1.35% 3.34% 0.99% 0.78% 3.49% 1.82% 2.20% 3.40% 1.42% 0.47% 0.27% 0.66% 0.21% 0.70% 0.49% Food Beverage & tobacco product Textile mills Textile product mills Apparel Leather & allied product Wood product Paper Printing & related activities Petroleum & coal products Chemical Plastics & rubber products Nonmetallic mineral product Primary metal Fabricated metal product Machinery Computer & electronic product Electrical equipment, appliance Transportation equipment Furniture & related product Miscellaneous 0.03 0.02 −0.31 0.17 0.25 −0.10 −0.59 −0.47 0.27 −0.59 0.08 −0.24 −0.33 −1.17 −0.18 −0.31 0.67 0.11 −0.80 −0.11 0.71 (0.24) (0.41) (0.58) (0.16) (0.32) (0.27) (0.23)** (0.22)** (0.11)** (0.25)** (0.19) (0.15) (0.17)** (0.26)*** (0.14) (0.18)* (0.26)** (0.20) (0.28)*** (0.14) (0.12)*** 239 −890 −970 −905 227 −1026 −1008 −728 −60 −1007 143 −240 −723 −1053 979 −211 2185 −574 −243 −584 574 (311) (396)** (344)*** (312)*** (434) (380)*** (329)*** (303)** (119) (371)*** (317) (194) (287)** (331)*** (555)* (260) (910)** (256)** (578) (155)*** (194)*** 1.28% 1.28% 1.28% 1.28% 0.10% 0.11% 0.19% 0.63% 0.28% 2.18% 0.35% 1.13% 1.38% 1.96% 0.20% Other industries Specialty trade contractors Motor vehicle & parts dealers Food & beverage stores General merchandise stores Credit intermediation & related Insurance carriers & related Professional, scientific & techn. Management of companies Administrative & support Educational services Ambulatory health care Hospitals Nursing & residential care Food services & drinking places Religious, grantmaking, civic 0.10 −0.06 0.03 −0.07 −0.15 −0.22 −0.18 −0.15 −0.07 0.02 0.07 −0.13 0.14 0.00 −0.04 (0.06)* (0.06) (0.12) (0.06) (0.08)* (0.12)* (0.09)* (0.13) (0.11) (0.11) (0.05) (0.11) (0.05)*** (0.04) (0.04) −825 −797 −786 −549 −277 −340 −4099 −1514 −3151 −81 −14 463 107 −2854 14 (576) (315)** (412)* (288)* (350) (389) (1717)** (540)*** (1245)** (605) (528) (477) (191) (1218)** (187) Notes: For manufacturing industries, we modify Eq. (1) so that each industry has a separate price coefficient. For non-manufacturing industries, we estimate Eq. (1) separately for each industry. Industry growth is from 1998 to 2006. See Table 3's notes for further details. M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 113 Table 5 Alternative regressions exploring the relationship between regulation and manufacturing employment. ln Electricity price ln Electricity price*electricity index Right to work*labor/capital Nonattainment county Nonattainment*pollution index No pollution monitor No monitor*pollution index County pair F.E. Industry–year F.E. State–year F.E. County F.E. R2 N All counties County trends PM regulation CO regulation Instrumental variables Instrumental variables County fixed effects 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 67.9 (55.7) −416.4** (176.3) 4416.4*** (1209.1) 142.3*** (36.4) −589.2*** ( 156.0) −83.5*** ( 16.0) 330.2*** (45.7) Y Y Y 3.0 (188.9) −1214.4** (515.3) 9429.0*** (2851.7) 113.0** (45.3) −519.5*** (197.8) −91.6** (45.1) 542.8*** (110.3) Y Y Y 23.2 (193.3) −1417.2*** (443.6) 7750.6** (3910.6) 58.5 (115.6) −481.3 (333.2) −122.7** (50.7) 574.3*** (99.7) Y Y Y −187.7 (212.7) −1149.7*** (387.1) 7965.4* (4057.2) 510.7** (236.4) −1150.1 (877.5) −64.4 (135.7) 947.7*** (164.5) Y Y Y −3648.4** (1598.4) −2839.2 (2048.7) 8302.9*** (3060.3) 49.6 (55.9) −362.4* (193.1) −130.4** (59.1) 602.4*** (140.6) Y Y Y −469.6* (250.9) −748.2** (373.3) 8540.1** (3527.9) 79.6 (75.2) −470.3** (195.6) −81.0 (57.7) 455.9*** (90.1) Y Y Y 0.37 3,010,812 0.37 1,120,243 0.34 1,100,173 0.34 1,104,840 0.43 798,208 0.39 185,828 540.6*** (195.1) −1217.2** (516.9) 9432.2*** (2858.7) 65.6 (41.3) −519.2*** (198.2) −109.3*** (20.5) 542.8*** (110.5) Y Y Y 0.38 182,507 Notes: Column (2) includes linear time trends for the county variables (population in 1970, miles to CBD, area of county, 1990 housing values). See Table 3's notes for further details. electricity prices and to environmental regulation. Establishments that are energy intensive avoid the high electricity price counties. We cannot reject the hypothesis that there is no correlation between labor regulation and the establishment count. In column (3), we switch the dependent variable to the log of the establishment count. In this case, we find that there are more labor-intensive establishments clustering on the Right-to-Work side of the border. We continue to find evidence that electricity prices and ozone regulation are determinants of establishments. In columns (4) and (5) of Table 6, we report regression results for two measures of facility size: the ratio of workers per establishment, and its log. Bigger firms avoid the high electricity price county. Surprisingly, we find no statistically significant correlation between a county's Right-to-Work status and the size of facilities even for labor-intensive industries. Based on the results in column (4), smaller firms in high ozone industries are clustering in counties that do not monitor ozone. 4.3. Summary of results We summarize our findings in Table 7. In this table, we use our regression results from Table 3's column (1) and we report our estimated effects for electricity prices, labor regulation and environmental regulation. Recall that the interaction terms between electricity prices, labor regulation and environmental regulation and the industry specific attributes listed in Table 2 play a key role in our estimates of Eq. (1). In Table 7, we exploit this information to report how the effects of electricity prices and regulation vary with industry attributes. The most intensive industries in electricity, labor and pollution are much more sensitive to their respective policies. For example, the electricity price elasticity is almost negative two for electricity intensive industries, such as primary metals, but is inelastic and only weakly significant for the average industry in our sample. Labor and environmental policies have huge effects on their most intensive Table 6 Regulation and establishment characteristics. ln Electricity price ln Price *electricity index Right to work*labor/capital Nonattainment county Nonattainment *pollution index No pollution monitor No monitor *pollution index R2 N Notes: See Table 3's notes for details. Employees Establishments Log establishment Workers per establishment Log (workers per establishment) 1 2 3 4 5 6.3** (2.8) −38.1** (14.8) −14.1 (78.4) 3.0*** (1.1) −17.9*** (5.8) −1.6 (1.0) 13.5*** (2.9) 0.44 1,120,243 0.12* (0.07) −0.57*** (0.20) 7.46*** (1.82) 0.05*** (0.02) −0.17** (0.08) −0.05* (0.03) 0.25*** (0.06) 0.77 947,301 10.9** (4.4) −42.3*** (12.0) −117.0 (115.6) −4.3*** (1.6) 12.3* (6.4) 4.4*** (1.5) −11.2* (6.4) 0.14 947,290 0.12** (0.06) −0.59*** (0.14) 2.34 (1.73) −0.03 (0.02) 0.08 (0.10) 0.01 (0.02) −0.06 (0.07) 0.28 947,290 114.6 (180.3) −1217.6** (515.8) 9430.7*** (2851.9) 87.4* (46.1) −519.1*** (197.7) −99.9** (44.4) 542.8*** (110.3) 0.36 1,120,243 114 M.E. Kahn, E.T. Mansur / Journal of Public Economics 101 (2013) 105–114 Table 7 Summary table of main results. Regulation or price Least intensive Electricity (e.g. Computers) Electricity priceElasticity Labor Right-to-workPercentage 0.172 (0.270) 2.1%*** (0.6%) (e.g. Apparel) Ozone nonattainment percentage 13.1%* (6.9%) −15.0%** (6.6%) Most intensive (e.g. Primary metals) −0.227* (0.134) (e.g. Petroleum/coal) Pollution Ozone no monitorPercentage Average intensity −1.652*** (0.621) (e.g. Apparel) 21.9%*** (6.6%) 67.0%*** (20.3%) (e.g. Petroleum/coal) 4.3% (4.7%) −5.8% (5.9%) −64.6%*** (24.5%) 66.3%*** (14.1%) Notes: We report elasticities and percentages based on Table 3, Column (1) estimates and Table 1's average number of workers per observation. Standard errors are reported in parentheses using the delta method. Average intensity is a worker-weighted average of the county–industry–year observations in our sample and equals 0.28 and 0.11 for the normalized electricity and ozone indices, respectively. See Table 3's notes for further details. industries, apparel and coal/petroleum respectively, but hardly matter for the average industry. As shown in Table 3, the electricity and labor policy findings are robust to functional form assumptions but are mixed for environmental policies. 5. Conclusion The basic logic of cost minimization offers strong predictions concerning where different manufacturing industries will cluster across U.S. counties as a function of regulatory policies and input prices. Using a unified framework that exploits within county-pair variation in locational attributes, we have documented that labor-intensive industries locate in anti-union areas, energy-intensive industries locate in low electricity price counties and high polluting industries seek out low regulation areas. The environmental regulation finding is sensitive to functional form assumptions but previous studies have reported qualitatively similar evidence. Based on our findings, we conclude that energy prices are a significant determinant of locational choice for a handful of manufacturing industries such as primary metals. For the typical manufacturing industry, the electricity price effects are modest. Our analysis highlights the importance of studying the marginal effects of energy regulation, labor regulation and environmental regulation at the same time. Republican “Red States” tend to have low electricity prices, and be Right to Work states while Democratic “Blue States” tend to have higher electricity prices and support union rights. Both types of states are roughly likely to have counties assigned to pollution non-attainment status. This paper's empirical strategy has allowed us to estimate the marginal and total effects of this bundle of policies. We anticipate that future research will access census micro data for manufacturing plants. Such data would allow researchers to make more progress on the likely mechanisms underlying the aggregate effects that we report. At the extensive margin, do incumbent firms exit areas where environmental regulations tighten and electricity prices increase? Or, do existing firms respond by reducing their output and hence their consumption of inputs? Anticipating the persistence of these policies do firms make investments to alter their use of the relatively more costly input? Appendix A. Supplementary data Supplementary data to this article can be found online at http:// dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.03.002. References Becker, Randy, Henderson, Vernon, 2000. Effects of air quality regulations on polluting industries. Journal of Political Economy 108 (2), 379–421. Berman, Eli, Bui, Linda T.M., 2001. Environmental regulation and labor demand: evidence from the South Coast Air Basin. Journal of Public Economics 79 (2), 265–295. Bernard, Andrew B., Jensen, J. Bradford, Schott, Peter K., 2006. Survival of the best fit: exposure to low-wage countries and the (uneven) growth of U.S. manufacturing plants. Journal of International Economics 68 (1), 219–237. Carlton, Dennis, 1983. The location and employment choices of new firms: an econometric model with discrete and continuous endogenous variables. The Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (3), 440–449. Chirinko, Robert S., Wilson, Daniel J., 2008. State investment tax incentives: a zero-sum game? Journal of Public Economics 92 (12), 2362–2384. Davis, Steven J., Faberman, R. Jason, Haltiwanger, John, 2006. The flow approach to labor markets: new data sources and micro–macro links. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (3), 3–26. Davis, Steven, Grim, Cheryl, Haltiwanger, John, Streitwieser, Mary, 2008. Electricity pricing to U.S. manufacturing plants, 1963–2000. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 13778. Deschenes, Olivier, 2012. Climate policy and labor markets. In: Fullerton, Don, Wolfram, Catherine (Eds.), The Design and Implementation of U.S. Climate Policy. University of Chicago Press. Dube, Arindrajit, Lester, T. William, Reich, Michael, 2010. Minimum wage effects across state borders: estimates using contiguous counties. The Review of Economics and Statistics 92 (4), 945–964. Dumais, Guy, Ellison, Glen, Glaeser, Edward, 2002. Geographic concentration as a dynamic process. The Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (2), 193–204. Ellison, Glen, Glaeser, Edward, 1999. The geographic concentration of industry: does natural advantage explain agglomeration? American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 89 (2), 311–317. Greenstone, Michael, 2002. The impacts of environmental regulation on industrial activity. Journal of Political Economy 110 (6), 1175–1219. Greenstone, Michael, Hornbeck, Richard, Moretti, Enrico, 2010. Identifying agglomeration spillovers: evidence from million-dollar plants. Journal of Political Economy 118 (3), 536–598. Holmes, Thomas, 1998. The effect of state policies on the location of manufacturing: evidence from state borders. Journal of Political Economy 106 (4), 667–705. Isserman, Andrew, Westervelt, James, 2006. 1.5 Million missing numbers: overcoming employment suppression in the county business patterns data. International Regional Science Review 29 (3), 311–335. Joskow, Paul L., 1989. Regulatory failure, regulatory reform and structural change in the electric power industry. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics. 125–199. Joskow, Paul L., 2006. Markets for power in the U.S.: an interim assessment. The Energy Journal 27 (1), 1–36. Kahn, Matthew E., 1997. Particulate pollution trends in the United States. Regional Science and Urban Economics 27 (1), 87–107. Kahn, Matthew E., Mansur, Erin T., 2010. How do energy prices, and labor and environmental regulations affect local manufacturing employment dynamics? A regression discontinuity approach. NBER Working Paper 16538. Killian, Lutz, 2008. The economic effects of energy price shocks. Journal of Economic Literature 46 (4), 871–909. Linn, Joshua, 2009. Why do energy prices matter? The role of interindustry linkages in U.S. manufacturing. Economic Inquiry 47 (3), 549–567. Neal, Derek, 1995. Industry-specific human capital: evidence from displaced workers. Journal of Labor Economics 13 (4), 653–677. Walker, Reed, 2012. The Transitional Costs of Sectoral Reallocation: Evidence from the Clean Air Act and the Workforce. Working paper.
Purchase answer to see full attachment
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following Studypool's honor code & terms of service.

Explanation & Answer

Hello, here is the solution. Let me know if you need edits. Feel free to invite me in the future. Cheers!😀

Running head: REFEREE REPORT

1

Referee Report
Student Name
University
Course Title
Date

REFEREE REPORT

2

Background and Motivation
In America, manufacturing companies are among the largest job providers. The jobs
provided by the manufacturing industry sustain the living standards of thousands of American
households. The United States employment market is an environment characterized by a high
level of competitiveness where opportunities for less qualified workers are increasingly rare.
However, the American manufacturing industry helps these workers by offering them jobs
with considerable wages (Kahn & Mansur, 2013). In the context of globalization, American
manufacturing companies face challenges regarding competition coming from outsid e the
country. The overcome these important challenges, manufacturing companies adopt different
strategies. Among these strategies, the relocation of production units is the most privileged.
While some companies opt for foreign territories, others move from one American territory to
another. These movements within the American territory shape the economic attractiveness of
the American counties and influence lives of eleven millions of Americans (Kahn & Mansur,
2013). In this study, the authors focus on the geographical clustering of the United States
manufacturing companies keeping in mind the prominent role played by this phenomenon in
employment repartition. The authors try to identify the factors motivating the reasons
motivating manufacturing companies in their choices of locating or relocating their industries
in one region over a...

Related Tags