Difference of Environmental Policy Process in China from Other States Paper

User Generated

Qvzv01

Writing

Description

1. How has Xi Jinping changed or manipulated the political system for his own ends, according to Gueorguiev?

2. What ramifications do these changes have for the future of elite-run politics, and politics in general, in China?

3. Why is the environmental policy process in China different from the norm in other states?

4. What happened to create what Chen and Lees call “Authoritarian Environmentalism” in China? How is this manifested through the new green urbanization initiatives?

5. What do both of these articles tell us more generally about the role of the state in China, and its strengths and weaknesses?

Unformatted Attachment Preview

S peci al feature China per spectives Dictator’s Shadow Chinese Elite Politics Under Xi Jinping D I MITA R D . GU EO RG UIE V ABSTRACT: President Xi Jinping is arguably the most powerful Chinese leader since Chairman Mao. Recent constitutional revisions and a midterm leadership reshuffle has only substantiated the fear that Xi, like Mao, has no intention of handing over power to a future successor. Does Xi’s rise signal an end to collective leadership and does a stronger president translate into a weaker party? In this article, I review the methods by which Xi has come to consolidate power as well as the implications for Chinese elite politics in the future. Drawing insights from the comparative literature, I question the zero-sum relationship between executive and institutional strength. Although Xi has certainly amassed unprecedented personal power, it has not necessarily come at the expense of the Party. Instead, the dangers of Xi Jinping’s power grab are more likely to result from a chilling effect on dissenting opinions and thinning out of the leadership pipeline, each of which is likely to undermine governing capacity over the medium to long-term. KEYWORDS: China, Authoritarian Regimes, Elite Politics, Power Sharing, Collective Leadership, Institutions, Succession. O ne-man rule is cited as a common source of regime breakdown—what Milan Svolik (2012) refers to as “failures in power-sharing.” The reason why power-sharing under authoritarian rule is so hard is self-evident: in the absence of democratic competition there is little to deter incumbent leaders from abusing their office at the expense of other elites. Against this backdrop, China’s postMao period stands out as an example of relatively effective power-sharing, or what the ruling Chinese Communist Party (CCP) refers to as “collective leadership.” During this 40-year period, we have observed between three and six peaceful transitions of power, from one incumbent to another. (1) Rapid concentration of power in President Xi Jinping has raised serious questions about the efficacy and durability of Chinese power sharing institutions, leading some observers to conclude that “collective leadership [in China] is dead.” (2) In this article, I push back on such claims by reviewing China’s leadership norms and institutions as well as how they are being challenged. Building on the work of Slater (2003), I start from the premise that personalisation and institutionalisation under autocracy are not a zero-sum game. In the case of China, ambiguous leadership institutions, coupled with elite complicity, have in fact facilitated Xi’s power grab. Instead, I argue that the dangers of personalisation are more likely to concern future governance challenges. First, departure from collective decisionmaking procedures, coupled with increasing censorship, is likely to discourage critical voices from participating in the political discourse. This chilling effect will make it harder for the regime to anticipate future challenges and avoid unnecessary policy blunders. Second, anti-corruption purges, combined with an apparent desire to seed loyalists, has either discouraged or prevented younger contenders from moving up through the ranks, effectively thinning out the pipeline of future leaders. This potential shortage of qualified contenders will affect the Party irrespective of whether Xi remains in office. No.2018/1-2 • china perspectives Chinese elite politics under Xi Jinping In explaining the CCP’s durability, scholars point to China-specific leadership institutions, norms, and procedures, which in theory facilitate stable power sharing. In particular, prior research points to: organisational fragmentation that prevents incumbents from monopolising power (Lampton and Lieberthal 1992; Xu 2011), age and term limits that prevent incumbents from entrenching themselves in office (Ma 2016; Nathan 2003; Shirk 2002; Manion 1993), along with procedures for collective decision-making that incorporate lower levels through reciprocal accountability (Shirk 1993; Hu 2014). Recent consolidation and personalisation of power around Xi Jinping raises serious questions about each of the above. Over the last five years, Xi has resurrected the titles of “Core Leader” (Miller 2016), immortalised his ideological “thought” into the CCP constitution (Miller 2017), (3) and revised the national constitution to remove term limits for the office of the presidency. (4) How did Xi Jinping accumulate such an unprecedented amount of personal power and what does it mean for the future of elite politics in China? I begin by outlining the boundaries of collective leadership and examine just how far Xi has pushed them. Like Slater, who examined packing, rigging, and circumventing of Malaysia’s leadership institutions under Mohamad Mahathir, I focus on challenges posed by Xi Jinping towards the separation 1. Hua Guofeng briefly succeeded Mao Zedong before relinquishing control to Deng Xiaoping. Deng initially designated two successors, Hu Yaobang and Zhao Ziyang. After helping bring both down, Deng fully handed the reigns to Jiang Zemin. Jiang relinquished power to Hu Jintao in 2002, who then handed it to Xi Jinping in 2012. 2. For example, see: Jeremy Page and Chun Han Wong. “Xi Jinping Is Alone at the Top and Collective Leadership ‘Is Dead’,” The Wall Street Journal, 25 October 2017, www.wsj.com/articles/chinasxi-elevated-to-mao-status-1508825969 (accessed on 15 November 2017). 3. The CCP added Deng’s name and thought to the constitution after he died in 1997. 4. “China’s National Legislature Adopts Constitutional Amendment,” Xinhua, 13 March 2018, www.xinhuanet.com/english/2018-03/11/c_137031606.htm (accessed on 15 March 2018). p e e r - r e v i e w e d a r t i c l e 17 S p e ci a l feat ure Table 1 – Leadership Positions Held by Xi Jinping Leadership body Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party Central Military Commission of the CCP Central Leading Group for Taiwan Affairs Presidency of the People’s Republic of China Central Military Commission of the PRC Central Leading Group for Foreign Affairs, National Security Central Leading Group for Financial and Economic Work PRC National Security Committee Central Leading Group for Comprehensively Deepening Reforms Central Leading Group for Network Security and Information Techology Leading Group for Deepening Reform of National Defense and Military PLA Joint Operations Command Center Title Tenure since Precedent Gen. Secretary Chair Head President Chair Head Head Chair Chair Head Head Cmdr. in Chief 2012.11 2012.11 2012.11 2013.03 2013.03 2013.03 2013.03 2013.11 2013.11 2014.02 2014.02 2016.04 Y Y Y Y Y Y Y new new new new new Note: Based on Li (2016) and expanded upon records from China Vitae Research Library. of powers, norms surrounding succession, and procedures for collective decision-making in China. Although each of these features are aimed at constraining despotic rule, each is also subordinate to the primary goal of political domination by the CCP. As such, we should allow for the possibility that personalisation of power can occur even if a ruling party’s key institutions are still intact (Slater 2003). Circumventing the separation of powers The 17th Party Congress Communique from 2007 defines collective leadership as “a system with a division of responsibilities among individual leaders to prevent arbitrary decision-making by a single top leader.” (5) In stark contrast, the first PB meeting of the 19th Congress in October 2017 concluded that “centralised and unified leadership by the Party is the highest principle of the leadership.” Most recently, Xi Jinping’s outgoing anti-corruption czar, Wang Qishan, penned an essay in People’s Daily outlining “problems with separating party and state,” and explaining why future challenges would require doing away with this division. (6) Anticipating Wang’s thesis, Xi Jinping is actively blurring the divisions between politics, economics, and military affairs since stepping into office in 2012. This distortion of boundaries is clearly visible in the number and span of leadership positions currently held by Xi Jinping, referred to by some as the “chairman of everything.” (7) By Cheng Li’s (2016) count, Xi now holds a total of 12 top posts in the country’s most powerful leadership bodies (see Table 1). With the exception of the core titles of General Party Secretary, President, and Chairman of the Central Military Commission, the remaining positions fall into the category of “leading groups,” which are informal bodies of extreme power—often having more influence than respective ministries. The mere presence of so many leading groups seems itself a contradiction to collective leadership, separation of power, and constitutional authority more broadly. Yet, this is precisely what they are designed to do, i.e., overcome bureaucratic or organisational barriers, pool resources, and push through policy agendas (Miller 2008). Whether intended or not, CCP leaders, beginning with Mao, (8) have routinely taken advantage of the leading groups to bypass opposition and assert control; Xi Jinping is just the latest. What is perhaps different, however, is how Xi’s leading groups cross-cut and overlap multiple policy arenas, some of which have traditionally fallen 18 under the purview of other Politburo Standing Committee (PBSC) members and State Council ministers. For instance, the vaguely named Central Leading Group for Comprehensively Deepening Reforms conceivably oversees anything from financial markets to environmental regulation. At the same time, however, Xi has not appropriated portfolios that were not his for the taking. As Table 1 summarises, seven of Xi’s titles have precedents, insofar as they were previously held by Hu Jintao, and by Jiang Zemin before him. The remaining five offices were conjured up during Xi’s first term in office, and there is nothing in formal or informal party guidelines that discourages such action. For instance, the National Security Commission gives Xi indirect control over both foreign and domestic security, without expressly taking over those portfolios. Similarly, Xi’s most recent title, Commander-in-Chief of “PLA Joint Operations,” lays claim to new political territory, as there were no formal “joint operations” under previous administrations. In other words, rather than overtly breaking down fences, Xi Jinping appears to be re-drawing the bounds and meaning of institutional power-sharing. To be sure, the point here is not in any way to downplay Xi’s political bravado, but rather to highlight the nuanced signalling game Xi is playing. Put differently, if Xi wanted to demonstrate his dominance and the end of collective leadership, he might simply appropriate the National Energy Commission (headed by Li Keqiang) or the Central Commission for Discipline Inspection (CCDI, now run by Zhao Leji). He has not done so, at least not yet. Instead, Xi has circumvented collective leadership through the institution of informal leading groups, a practice that predates his tenure and collective leadership more broadly. 5. Hu Jintao, 以改革创新精神全面推进党的建设新的伟大工程 (Yi gaige chuangxin jingshen quanmian tuijin dang de jianshe xin de weida gongcheng, Promoting comprehensive Party building in the spirit of reform and innovation), 17th Chinese Communist Party Congress, 15 October 2007, cpc.people.com.cn/GB/104019/104098/6379184.html (accessed on 15 November 2017). 6. Wang Qishan, 开启新时代 踏上新征程 (Kaiqi xin shidai ta shang xin zhengcheng, Opening a new era, stepping out on a new path), People’s Daily, 7 November 2017, paper.people.com.cn/ rmrb/html/2017-11/07/nw.D110000renmrb_20171107_1-02.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). 7. For instance, see: Javier Hernandez, “China’s ‘Chairman of Everything’: Behind Xi Jinping’s Many Titles,” The New York Times, 25 October 2017, www.nytimes.com/2017/10/25/world/asia/chinaxi-jinping-titles-chairman.html (accessed on 15 November 2017). 8. In 1966, Mao Zedong installed loyalists to the Central Leading Small Group on the Cultural Revolution to oversee a mass youth uprising and a widespread purge of his rivals and CCP elite more broadly. During his tenure, Jiang Zemin repeatedly refashioned the Taiwan Affairs Leading Group, at times leaning on generals or diplomats, reflecting changes in his Cross-Straits strategy (Hsiao 2013). china perspectives • No.2018/1-2 Dimitar D. Gueorguiev – Dictator’s Shadow: Chinese Elite Politics under Xi Jinping Even if there is still some separation of power at the very top, Xi is dramatically reshaping the way power is organised just below. These effects are most vivid within the military. Though often seen as an arm of the CCP, the PLA has traditionally enjoyed a measure of autonomy from the political state, at times acting in violation of or even contradiction to the aims of the leadership (Cheung 2001). Since Xi took office, however, thousands of military personnel, including hundreds of senior officers, have been purged and the traditional system of regional command, a vestige of the PLA’s landbased limitations, has been scrapped and replaced with five theatres under the direct oversight of the Central Military Commission (CMC), headed by Xi. (9) The CMC itself was downsized from 11 members to seven, (10) and in December 2017, the CCP Central Committee (CCOM) announced that the People’s Armed Police Force (PAP), a force of more than 600,000 overseen by both the State Council and the CMC since 1982, would be put under the direct command of the CMC alone, beginning on 1 January 2018. Consolidation within China’s cabinet mirrors that of the military. As of March 2017, the State Council, chaired by Premier Li Keqiang, has been reduced from 35 members to 27. As in the case of the military, the merger of prominent ministries and the creation of new agencies and administrations is being touted on grounds of modernisation and efficiency. (11) This claim is not unwarranted. For instance, the recently proposed Banking and Insurance Regulatory Commission, a State Immigration Administration, and an International Development Cooperation Agency each address policy arenas that have only really emerged over the last decade. At the same time, and just as in the case of military restructuring, it is hard to ignore how changes within the governing cabinet are blurring the boundary between state and party. The Financial Stability and Development Committee (announced in November 2017), for instance, combines economic oversight with policymaking powers, each of which has traditionally been housed in separate kitchens (Naughton 2017). (12) Even more dramatically, a new National Supervision Commission (NSC) merges and absorbs the functions of the Ministry of Supervision (a state institution) within that of the CCDI (a party organ). (13) This new branch of government not only cements Xi Jinping’s signature anti-corruption crusade as permanent fixture of the party-state, its institutional rank—equal to that of the State Council and higher than the judicial organs—circumvents the most paramount division of power and rule of law. (14) Rigging the transfer of power The transfer of power in Chinese leadership politics has been guided in recent decades by three reinforcing norms, none of which are formally or legally outlined in the CCP’s or the PRC’s constitution (Wang and Vangeli 2016). The first, and arguably the most important, concerns age and term limits. The second and third are about the nomination and the grooming of future leaders, respectively. Below, I briefly review the origins of these succession norms and the degree to which they are being followed today. One of Deng Xiaoping’s pivotal reform efforts was rejuvenating the CCP ranks by persuading revolutionary leaders into retirement (Manion 1993). Although Deng refrained from adopting a specific age threshold for top leaders, age restrictions for provincial and ministerial-level leadership positions, along with fixed term limits, were adopted into the constitution. These efforts gradually culminated into norms for retirement, with lower-level leaders facing mandatory retirement at 60 and mid-level leaders in the Central Committee at 65 (Nathan 2003). The norm for top leaders is not inNo.2018/1-2 • china perspectives scribed in any rule book, but precedent suggests that incumbents may continue to serve when they are still 67, but not if they have reached 68, a practice widely known as the “seven-up, eight-down (qi shang, ba xia)” rule. (15) In practice, this norm, combined with the age demographics of upper-most leadership cohorts, has also constrained top leaders to two terms in office, which happens to coincide with the state positions. Rather than violating the age-based retirement norm, Xi is taking full advantage of it. Although many expected 69-year-old Wang Qishan, a key Xi ally and principal agent of Xi’s anti-corruption campaign, to stay in the PBSC, he officially retired from his party portfolio during the 19th Party Congress. (16) This, of course, did not prevent Wang from taking over the vicepresidency, a position that carries no age restriction. Furthermore, all 16 members from the 18th PBSC who had passed the age threshold were retired, freeing up slots for Xi loyalists, including the elevation of 67-year-old Li Zhanshu to the PBSC. Another, more ambiguous, set of norms concerns the selection and grooming of successors, a perennial source of friction and uncertainty in non-democratically constituted regimes. The CCP is thought to have made in-roads into this problem by extending the succession process across overlapping generations, whereby leaders-in-waiting take on key roles within the PBSC in advance of their expected promotion (Ma 2016). This staggered approach has two important implications. First, it means that future leaders are well-socialised into the leadership structure before taking formal positions. Second, it implies that although incumbents are constrained from directly naming their own successors they have considerable influence in nominating contenders to succeed one generation later. Importantly, therefore, adherence to the “seven-up, eight down” age norm implies that all members of the 19th PBSC, including Xi, are too old to carry on the mantle of General Party Secretary after 2022. (17) Xi’s predicament aside, the key takeaway of the 19th Party Congress was thus the curious absence of any leader-in-waiting. A surprise constitutional overhaul, conducted behind the scenes of the 2018 national legislative session, helped clear things up by removing term limits for the office of President (also held by Xi Jinping). As with the vice-presidency, the presidency carries no age re9. “China’s Military Regrouped into Five PLA Theater Commands,” Xinhua, 1 February 2016, www.xinhuanet.com/english/2016-02/01/c_135065429.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). 10. Charlotte Gao, “Has Xi Fully Consolidated His Power Over the Military?” The Diplomat, 8 January 2018, thediplomat.com/2018/01/has-xi-fully-consolidated-his-power-over-the-military/ (accessed on 15 January 2018). 11. Government Overhaul Plan, mp.weixin.qq.com/s/_mG6KoJHKvXPpE6YE3zh9w (accessed on 15 March 2018). 12. “China Establishes Financial Stability and Development Committee,” Xinhua, 8 November 2017, www.xinhuanet.com/english/2017-11/08/c_136737949.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). 13. There is no question as to the CCP’s predominance within the NSC. At the national level 14 out of the 17 leadership members come with affiliations to either the Central or provincial Disciplinary Inspection Commissions (DIC). At the provincial level more than 170 of the roughly 300 provincial committee members have ties to provincial DICs. Author’s calculations based on provincial reports. 14. See: Charlotte Gao, “China Plans to Amend Its Constitution,” The Diplomat, 28 December 2017, thediplomat.com/2017/12/china-plans-to-amend-its-constitution/ (accessed on 18 January 2018). 15. Wang and Vangeli (2016) refer to this as the “Li Ruihuan Clause” because it was the uncomfortable task of retiring Li Ruihuan in 1997—then 68 years old—that encouraged members of the 15th Congress, with strong pressure from Jiang Zemin, to lower the formal retirement age of top leaders from 70 to 68. 16. See: Wang Xiangwei, “Despite Retirement, Xi’s Right-Hand Man Wang Qishan is Still Within Arm’s Reach,” South China Morning Post, 2 December 2017, www.scmp.com/week-asia/opinion/article/2122250/despite-retirement-xis-right-hand-man-wang-qishan-still-within (accessed on 15 December 2017). 17. Zhao Leji, the youngest member, will be 65 in 2022 and can look forward to no longer than one more term in the PBSC, which ought to disqualify him from the top spot. 19 S p e ci a l feat ure Table 2 – 19th Party Congress Politburo (Standing Committe Excluded) Member Hu Chunhua Ding Xuexiang Chen Min'er Li Qiang Huang Kunming Li Hongzhong Li Xi Cai Qi Chen Quanguo Guo Shengkun Chen Xi Yang Xiaodu Liu He Wang Chen Xu Qiliang Sun Chunlan Yang Jiechi Zhang Youxia Age 54 55 57 58 61 61 61 62 62 63 64 64 65 67 67 67 67 67 Jiang Hu – ✔ ✔ ✔ – – ✔ – ✔ ✔ – – 团派). Han Zheng is most closely associated with former General Secre- Xi ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ – ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ ✔ – – CCOM entry 2007 2017 2012 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2012 2012 2012 2012 2012 2002 2002 2007 2007 2007 Note: I treat the incumbent leader during entry into the central committee as a key indicator for a possible factional tie. Then, I consider shared working experience and personal connections as confirmatory. In the absence of confirmatory links, I do not assign a factional tie. Based on records from China Vitae Research Library. striction, meaning that Xi Jinping can comfortably and legally retain his position as head of state after 2022. A future accommodation for Xi to hold concurrent control of the Party’s General Secretary position beyond 2022, despite his advanced age, will thus be easily defendable. tary Jiang Zemin’s “Shanghai clique,” while Zhao Leji and Li Zhanshu are both seen as part of Xi’s emerging “New Zhijiang army.” The seventh member, Wang Hu-ning, is a low-profile academic who has connections with each of the above groupings, having helped pen Jiang’s “Three Represents,” Hu’s “Scientific Development,” and Xi’s “Socialist Evolution” theories, each of which is now enshrined in the CCP constitution. Although the PBSC appears roughly balanced, as already noted, according to the “seven up, eight down” rule, practically the entire current PBSC will have to retire in 2022. The fulcrum of balance is therefore more likely to be found in the enlarged PB, which is heavily stacked in Xi’s favour. Among the 18 current PB members who are not in the standing committee, only three could convincingly be described as members of either Hu’s or Jiang’s respective cliques, compared to nine who could be labelled as part of Team Xi (see Table 2). (18) Such groupings are problematic, both conceptually and analytically. Specifically, identifying a factional affiliation often boils down to determining a person’s expressed or perceived loyalty towards a patron (Shih 2008). The problem, of course, is deciding whether those expressing loyalty to an incumbent leader are genuine clients, since not demonstrating such allegiance is not much of an option. Which individuals made it into the PB is also only half the story. The recent career jolts to three leaders tied to Hu Jintao is a case in point. Sun Zhengcai’s removal just before the 19th Congress—at only 54 years old and an obvious Hu protégé—alongside the unceremonious early retirement of Li Yuanchao and the quiet demotion of Liu Qibao, two prominent Tuanpai kingpins, signal with very little ambiguity that Hu Jintao’s remaining influence within the CCP leadership is token at best. (19) In short, while the current PB reflects some semblance of balance, when we parse through the optics, it becomes quite clear that Xi Jinping has taken full advantage of his position to tip the scales sharply in his favour. Packing the balance of power Dampening dissent In addition to institutional divisions and succession norms, many point to the role of factional politics as providing a de facto balance of power (Cai and Treisman 2006). Factions revolve around CCP leaders, who play the role of patrons, leveraging their position of power to cultivate personal networks of clients (Nathan 1973). Importantly, CCP norms around the transfer of power facilitate factional competition by creating room for more than one patron at a time; namely, the incumbent leader and the predecessor. That is, by preventing incumbents from hand-picking their own successor but allowing them to appoint prospective leaders who might one day succeed their successor, CCP norms extend the shadow of the incumbent at least two generations ahead. In theory, this iterative process ought to ensure some balance of personal power within the top echelon of leaders (Ma 2016). Ironically, although Hu Chunhua is highly unlikely to be promoted in the future, his presence as one of only three PB members young enough to be named General Secretary in 2022 is at least a symbolic nod to the idea of staggered succession, insofar as he is widely seen as having been Hu Jintao’s nominee from 2012. The present PBSC features representatives from each of China’s most powerful factions. Premier Li Keqiang and Vice Premier Wang Yang both hail from the Chinese Communist Youth League and are seen as having ties to former General Secretary Hu Jintao’s “League faction” (Tuanpai 20 The relative ease with which Xi Jinping has refashioned and reconstituted the institutional infrastructure raises questions about the internal procedures underpinning collective leadership; namely that of Inner-Party Democracy (Lin 2002; Hu 2010). The concept, admittedly vague, rests in the belief that lower levels of power, despite being selected by the top leaders, exercise some influence over top leaders and decisions through a process referred to as “reciprocal accountability” (Shirk 1993). Although reciprocal accountability has not been directly demonstrated in China, the process by which the CCOM ratifies PB decisions and appointments is codified in the constitution. (20) 18. There is no clear-cut way to measure factional alignments. While some look at home town and schooling experience, others prioritise common work experience. I treat the incumbent leader during entry into the central committee, widely seen as the inner circle of the CCP, as a key indicator for a possible factional tie. Then, I consider shared working experience and personal connections as confirmation. In the absence of confirmatory links, I do not assign a factional tie. 19. Both Li and Liu were prominent members of the Chinese Communist Youth League, the organisational base for Hu Jintao’s Tuanpai faction. While Li has gone into early retirement, Liu and Zhang have been demoted from the PB positions in the 18th Congress to CCOM positions in the 19th, without much explanation. 20. Central Committee members have exercised institutional power vis-à-vis PB members in other communist systems such as the Soviet Union in 1957 and 1964, and by a no-confidence vote in Vietnam in 2014. china perspectives • No.2018/1-2 Dimitar D. Gueorguiev – Dictator’s Shadow: Chinese Elite Politics under Xi Jinping Whereas the 17th and 18th congresses were each preceded by an internal election, (21) selection in the 19th Congress was conducted by “face-to-face” consultation, with Xi Jinping personally meeting with 59 senior and retired leaders to seek their “suggestions.” Other senior leaders also held one-onone sessions with 290 ministerial cadres and senior military officers. (22) To understand what this means procedurally as well as politically, it is worth briefly digressing for a review of internal polls and consultation. There are two aspects to internal CCP election procedures that set them far apart from elections typical in Western democratic contexts. First, they are secret, so the outcome can never be independently verified. Second, Chinese internal elections are not contests among competing candidates. Instead, they operate as straw polls, based on a menu drafted by the PBSC, from which voters can identify who they would not want to be promoted. In October 2017, for instance, roughly 8 percent of proposed candidates for the 19th CCOM were eliminated by negative selection. (23) This approach departs from positive selection in two important ways. First, it biases against the rise of popular candidates, a principle that is a mainstay of collective leadership (Gueorguiev and Schuler 2016). Second, negative voting allows voters to knock off multiple names at once, which makes it difficult for voters to coordinate on a preferred candidate. In practice, negative selection delivers a range of least bad options, thereby empowering the PBSC to mix and match rather than having to adopt a set meal. Consultation is a different decision-making process but relies on roughly the same principles and leans even more sharply in the same top-heavy direction. As in negative voting, its key premise is that decision-makers set the agenda by defining the proposed list of candidates. Similarly, consultation also makes it difficult for the input providers to coordinate on preferred candidates because they are communicating vertically with the senior leaders but not horizontally among themselves. In effect, this provides senior leaders valuable information without the risk of bottom-up coordination. There is a cost, however. Not only does the compartmentalisation of input undermine the institutional basis of reciprocal accountability, face-to-face consultation, as opposed to a ballot, is unlikely to yield much in the way of unfiltered information. This risk increases with the personalisation of power, as any disagreement with nominees or policy proposals could be interpreted as disagreement with Xi Jinping himself. In other words, the move towards consultation, in combination with personalisation, will discourage elites from revealing preferences and speaking out. This, in turn, will compound the regime’s information problem, make it harder to anticipate opposition, and increase the chance of policy mistakes (Stromseth et al. 2017). The end of collective leadership? Does an ever stronger Xi Jinping translate into a weaker CCP? If we accept the idea that personalisation is antithetical to institutional survival, then Xi Jinping’s affront on collective leadership represents a substantial liability for CCP survival. At the same time, the zero-sum relationship between personalisation and institutionalisation is not waterproof. As Slater (2003) reminds us, highly institutionalised autocracies practice norms and procedures to constrain personal power, “but they are neither the sole nor the primary purposes of authoritarian institutions.” Ultimately, the raison d’etre of authoritarian institutions is not to prevent one-man rule, but to “supply a regime with the ‘infrastructural power’ necessary to implement its command over potential [opponents]” (Slater 2003: 82). No.2018/1-2 • china perspectives Applied to the case of China, there are at least three reasons why Xi’s consolidation of power might not have come at the direct expense of the Party. First, it is important to remember that the seeds of Xi’s unprecedented rise were sown well in advance of his taking office. Specifically, in reducing the PBSC from nine to seven members, five of whom would be too old to stay on past the 19th Congress, CCP elites expressed a preference for centralising and consolidating power in one leader. Furthermore, Xi’s ability to lead with a strong hand had everything to do with the fact that Hu Jintao handed over all key leadership positions in one clean transfer. As Joseph Fewsmith (2013) put it when commenting on the 18th Congress of 2012: Ironically the apparent concentration of power in the hands of those with strong ties to Jiang Zemin may permit Xi Jinping to emerge as a significantly stronger leader than Hu Jintao in 2002 and later years, even as this sort of political game could threaten over time the norms that have provided political stability in the Party. Surely, Xi Jinping has proven far more capable of personal aggrandisement than his peers may have ever anticipated, but it was a strongman they asked for. Second, by the end of Hu Jintao’s second term, elite politics in China had given way to a not-so-hidden competition between factional camps. Elite cohesion was so fraught that in the months leading up to the 18th Congress rumours floated of an armed coup. (24) In September of 2012, Xi Jinping himself went missing for more than two weeks, fuelling speculation of a power struggle. More generally, elites (not to mention average citizens) were openly bemoaning corruption, pollution, ballooning government debt, and widespread ideological apathy. In short, the CCP was in the grip of factional infighting, and at risk of losing its political compass. While many may have hoped for liberal reforms as the solution, the temptation of a strong leader proved highly attractive, even if it risked undermining collective leadership. Third, many of the festering problems from the end of Hu’s tenure have not been resolved. Today, China’s debt-to-GDP ratio has edged up to anywhere between 260%, according to official statistics, to around 320, based on independent assessments (Shih 2017). Similarly, SOE and banking sector reforms, not to mention lofty promises about rule of law, have made disappointingly little progress over the last five years—something Xi Jinping and his cabinet have acknowledged and promised to double up on, during speeches at the 2018 annual legislative session. All this comes at a time of heightened international insecurity and economic exposure for the Chinese state. The prospect of a third term for Xi Jinping, if anything, promises some continuity in policy direction and commitments. In short, Xi’s personalisation of power in China, as was the case with Mahathir in Malaysia, may have helped rather than undermined the Party’s position. 21. Under the original system, senior leaders, including outgoing CCOM and CCDI members, could nominate and ultimately vote for new CCOM and CCDI members based on a menu of candidates vetted by the PBSC. In 2012, this procedure was extended to include allowing these voters to vote on the members of the Politburo Standing Committee as well. See: Wang Xiangwei, “Despite Retirement, Xi’s Right-Hand Man Wang Qishan is Still Within Arm’s Reach,” op. cit. 22. “How China’s New Central Leadership are Elected,” Xinhua, 26 October 2017, www.xin huanet.com/english/2017-10/26/c_136707985.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). 23. Elimination in previous congresses is reported to have ranged between 5 and 10 percent. See: “At Least 8 pct of CPC Central Committee Nominees Voted Off,” Xinhua, 23 October 2017, www.webcitation.org/6x9ue2EXG (accessed on 1 November 2017) 24. While it is impossible to independently verify any of the rumours, the 2015 conviction of Zhou Yongkang, then China’s security chief, for the unprecedented crime of “non-organization political activities” lends credence to the notion that some form of extra-institutional contest for power likely occurred just prior to the 18th Congress. 21 S p e ci a l feat ure The argument here is not that personalisation is fully compatible with institutionalisation, but that when it comes to non-democratic rule there are higher priorities. Using Slater’s terminology, facilitating Xi’s consolidation arguably contributed to the CCP’s infrastructural power at a time when serious fissures were emerging. Whether the bet pays off in the long-term is an open question; but depicting Xi’s rise as coming fully at the expense of the CCP is misleading. (25) As institutional theorists and scholars of comparative politics have long argued, third-party enforcement is a definitional trait of institutions (Streeck and Thelen 2005), and in a one-party state there is none. Instead, the bite of authoritarian comes from the risk of violent power struggle that looms in the background (Boix and Svolik 2013). Xi’s cautious and tedious approach to circumventing, rigging, and packing demonstrates that he is mindful of such risks. For example, amending the constitution to abolish term limits for the presidency, a ceremonial position relative to that of general secretary, did more to signal Xi’s intentions than to facilitate them. Put simply, publicly floating and then having the entire legislature vote on rule change that could easily have been circumvented, and doing so five years in advance seems like a risky approach to committing what has been described as an institutional coup. (26) Finally, even though Xi’s affront on executive constraint has undoubtedly eroded the credibility of collective leadership, we should be realistic about how much has really been lost. The expectation that top leaders resign after two terms, for instance, has been severely discredited, yet, as discussed earlier, these norms were never formally adopted. Indeed, norms on term limits remained very much in question up through 2002. Ironically, their apparent enforcement in 2012, by vesting full power in Xi Jinping, set the stage for their corrosion. Indeed, if we accept the proposition that institutions for collective leadership, e.g., age-based retirement and staggered grooming, are intended to prevent personalisation, we must also acknowledge that such a system also puts incumbents in the difficult position of either resigning themselves to lame-duck status or ruthlessly trying to cannibalise their successor (Herz 1952). (27) Whereas Hu Jintao’s second term is illustrative of the former, Xi Jinping’s is clearly opting for the latter. The dictator’s shadow Even if the rise of a strongman was evident as early as 2012, it was not until March 2018 that the totality of Xi Jinping’s personalisation of power came into sharp relief. Though it is now abundantly clear that Xi Jinping is intent on a third term, his ability to stay in office that long is not a foregone conclusion, nor is it obvious that he plans to stay on indefinitely. Interestingly, on 12 March 2018, shortly after the NPC voted almost unanimously to abolish term limits, the state press went on the defensive, arguing that “the decision does not mean the end of the retirement system for Party and State leaders, nor does it imply lifetime tenure for any leader.” (28) While we can dismiss the comfort of the propaganda spin, it is worth considering: what are the circumstances under which leaders refuse to retire? The simple answer is always. An alternative explanation is that stepping down is inherently risky, as authoritarian leaders are far more likely to suffer violent ends than their democratic counterparts (Cox 2009). These risks do not subside when an incumbent retires. On the contrary, vulnerability increases as they are no longer in any position to protect themselves, or their friends. In short, there is good reason to suspect that authoritarian leaders 22 are deterred from stepping down by a lack of security for their lives and livelihood, and that of their friends and families (Albertus and Menaldo 2012; Debs 2016; Escriba-Folch 2013). (29) In the presence of an informal retirement age and fixed terms, such fears are clear and proximate from day one of an incumbent’s tenure. For someone like Xi, who has laid ruin to countless “flies” and several “tigers” since taking office, these worries are compounded every day as new knives are secretly sharpened for revenge. As Susan Shirk put it, “Xi has a big target on his back.” (30) Ironically, Xi might have been spared future retribution had he abided by party precedent and shielded former and current PB members from his anti-corruption campaign. By going after the likes of Zhou Yongkang and Sun Zhengcai, Xi has opened the floodgates and raised the prospect that his own associates, or perhaps even he himself, could one day be treated the same way. Seen in this light, Xi Jinping’s eponymous inscription in the CCP constitution is probably the closest one could get to an iron-clad guarantee for peaceful retirement. Put simply, from the perspective of late 2017, it would seem that Xi Jinping is untouchable, even if he steps down. This, ironically, may be the strongest justification for thinking that Xi might eventually retire voluntarily. However, even if Xi has secured his place in the sun, the same is not true for his family, friends, or policies, each of which will become vulnerable the moment Xi is no longer in charge. To protect the people and policies he holds dear, Xi will have to cast a long shadow that extends well beyond his eventual departure. Seeing the effects of what such a strategy could bring requires digging deeper into the party pipeline to examine the leadership cohorts of tomorrow. Seeding the pipeline As discussed earlier, Chinese leadership norms operate by front-loading the future into the present. For instance, allowing incumbents to groom their successor’s successor while discouraging them from hand-picking immediate successors gives incumbents a stake in the perpetuity of the regime without allowing them to dominate the present or the immediate future (Nathan 2003). By the same token, Xi Jinping’s power grab is just as consequential for downstream leadership cohorts, irrespective of his own current intentions. 25. It is perhaps worth noting that Mahathir, the personalising Malaysian dictator and protagonist of Slater’s 2003 article, orchestrated a smooth handover to a successor that same year. Members of the ruling UMNO wept at his announcement, imploring him to stay on. See: John Roberts, “Malaysian Prime Minister’s Sudden Resignation Points to Political Instability Ahead,” World Socialist Web Site, 5 July 2002, www.wsws.org/en/articles/2002/07/mala-j05.html (accessed on 15 March 2018). 26. While the CCP has a two-thirds majority in the National People’s Congress, it only holds a little over a third of the National People’s Political Consultative Conference, which also met during the annual legislative session in March 2018. Even if we are deeply sceptical about the independent power of China’s legislature, the national focal point of the meeting, combined with the presumed norms around tenure, means that this event was arguably the best opportunity for Xi’s opponents to mount a coordinated institutional challenge to his personalisation. 27. Jiang Zemin did considerable damage to Hu Jintao’s tenure by refusing to be a lame-duck leader prior to handing over power. 28. See: Zhang Jianfang, “Support for Amendments Belies Naysayers’ Prejudice: China Daily Comment,” China Daily, 12 March 2018, english.cctv.com/2018/03/12/ARTIBnPtQNnsXajsS6wTr0e 5180312.shtml?platform=hootsuite (accessed on 15 March 2018). 29. Consider the late Ahmadou Ahidjo of Cameroon, who voluntary resigned from power in 1982, only to be tried (in absentia) and sentenced to death in 1984, or the numerous others like him who live or have died in exile after stepping down from power. 30. Cited in Chris Buckley, “Xi Jinping Unveils China’s New Leaders but No Clear Successor,” The New York Times, 24 October 2017, www.nytimes.com/2017/10/24/world/asia/xi-jinping-china.html (accessed on 15 November 2017). china perspectives • No.2018/1-2 Dimitar D. Gueorguiev – Dictator’s Shadow: Chinese Elite Politics under Xi Jinping Figure 1 – Central Committee Age Distribution Alternate Central Committee 0 0 .05 .05 .1 .1 .15 .2 .15 Central Committee 40 50 60 70 40 45 50 19th Congress 18th Congress 17th Congress 16th Congress 55 60 65 Note: Based on records from China Vitae Research Library. Some potential downstream effects are visible if we look at the composition of the enlarged CCOM. (31) Roughly 64% of the members of the 19th CCOM are newcomers. The comparable proportions from 2012 and 2007 were only 48 and 50%, respectively. Whereas much of the turnover in 2007 was the consequence of retirement, a substantial portion of change in 2017 has been forced through corruption-related ousting. In total, 35 members (18 full and 17 alternates) from the 18th CCOM were punished for corruption. Only four members suffered a similar fate during Hu Jintao’s entire tenure. It is worth noting that each of the 35 members punished over the last five years was young enough to conceivably stay in office past 2022. (32) Overall, only two of the 376 members in the 19th CCOM were born in the 1970s. Compare that to 25 members born in the 1960s in the 17th CCOM, a decade earlier. Similarly, of the 204 19th CCOM members with full voting rights, only 32 were born after 1960 and therefore eligible to stay on for two full terms in 2022, compared to 70, a decade earlier. By nearly every metric available, the current CCOM is the oldest since 1992, when the current leadership institutions were first constituted. As illustrated in Figure 1, the age distribution of the 19th CCOM is heavily skewed to the left, meaning far fewer younger cadres—especially among alternate members, who represent the pipeline for CCP leadership in 2032. Indeed, the “Alternates” panel of Figure 1 suggests there is an entire generation of future leaders missing from the CCOM. The overall shift towards older cadres is partially offset by a small bump of “53-year-old and under” members, seen in the “Full” panel of Figure 1. In terms of continuity, these “bridging” cadres are interesting insofar as they have voting rights to determine the make-up of the PB during the 20th Congress in 2022 and are young enough to make it into the 22nd Congress in 2032. If Xi Jinping were worried about the postretirement period, it is precisely this group of cadres that would concern him, since their influence bridges across not one but two prospective leadership cohorts. No.2018/1-2 • china perspectives Overall, there are only 10 “bridging” cadres in the 19th Congress. Although we still do not know enough about this group to assign them to any particular camp, we can examine their respective career tracks. Lu Hao, who also happens to be the youngest of the group, rose rapidly through the ranks, building experience in both local government and central organisations. Lu has also been in the CCOM since 2012 and governor of Heilongjiang since 2013. As of this writing, however, Lu has received no further promotions, signalling a potential stall in his career as a once rising star. (33) By contrast, Zhang Guoqing was parachuted in to serve as mayor of Chongqing from an industry position, with no other political or administrative experience to speak of. The same distinction between stalled risers and powerful newcomers broadly applies to the rest of the bridging candidates, with veteran technocrats such as Li Ganjie, Ni Yuefeng, and Huang Shouhong finding themselves in roughly the same career grades they occupied a decade ago. By contrast, Liu Zhenli, Wu Zhenglong, Chen Jining, Jin Zhuanglong, and Meng Xiangfeng have all made swift entries into top leadership positions without the thick resumes that typically prop up the weighty portfolios they now hold. While it would be premature to say this latter set of bridging cadres are in Xi’s faction, they very likely owe their recent political fortunes to his patronage. The advanced overall age of the 19th CCOM warrants a closer look at younger members. The two youngest—both in the alternates pool—are 43year-old Cai Songtao and 47-year-old Zhou Qi. Cai heads the party committee of impoverished Lankao County in Henan, while Zhou is a prominent 31. The enlarged CCOM includes full and alternate members. 32. Four members—Wang Sanyun, Wu Aiying, Wang Min, Tian Xiusi—would have to have gotten promoted to the PB in order to stay on. 33. Moreover, Lu’s background as CCYL leader and Hu Jintao protégé are unlikely to win him any favours within Xi Jinping’s growing network. 23 S p e ci a l feat ure Table 3 – Bridging Candidates CCOM Member Age Lu Hao Liu Zhenli Li Ganjie Wu Zhenglong Zhang Guoqing Chen Jining Jin Zhuanglong Meng Xiangfeng Ni Yuefeng Huang Shouhong 50 53 53 53 53 53 53 53 53 53 Office Patron Governor, Heilongjiang Province Lt. Gen. of the PLA Minister of Environmental Protection Governor, Jiangsu Province Mayor, Chongqing Municipal Committee Mayor, Beijing Municipality Dep. Director Civil-Military Integration Comm. Dep. Director of General Office of the CCOM. General Administration of Customs Director, State Council Research Office Hu Xi N/A Xi Xi Xi Xi Xi N/A N/A Background Localities Military Environment Localities Aerospace Environment Aerospace Discipline Discipline Management Rising – Y – Y Y Y Y Y – – Note: I define "bridging candidates" as those who are young enough to enjoy the unique privilege of both influencing the make-up of the next congress in 2022 as well as making it into the 22nd Congress of 2032. A member is considered "rising" if he or she is consecutively promoted into new portfolios. Based on records from China Vitae Research Library. stem cell biologist at the Chinese Academy of Sciences. Both promotions highlight some of Xi’s top policy priorities for the next five years. (34) The scarcity of younger cadres within the CCOM implies that future leadership positions may be sourced from outside the traditional pipeline. We already have several examples. Beijing’s new mayor, Chen Jining, is an environmental scientist who rose to prominence primarily within academic circles, with only a brief two-year stint as Minister of Environmental Protection (2015-2017). Similarly, both Zhang Guoqing, the new mayor of Chongqing, and Jin Zhuanglong, deputy director of Civil-Military Integration, come straight from the military-aerospace industry. Again, these promotions not only mean more handpicked loyalists in important leadership positions, they also reinforce key themes in Xi’s policy rhetoric. For instance, Chen Jining’s placement in Beijing—notorious for its air pollution—is unlikely to have been a coincidence. (35) Similarly, technology investment, particularly in aerospace, is a key pillar in Xi’s military modernisation strategy. (36) More generally, the absence of young faces in the CCOM is disconcerting for the overall health of the CCP. First, it implies a dearth of eligible talent for filling future leadership positions. Second, it suggests we should expect more one-term leaders, who serve only five years in a top leadership position before retiring. This would shorten the political cycle and infuse more uncertainty into long-term policymaking. Furthermore, a dearth of younger officials means that even if talent were to be found, promotions would have to be fast-tracked through the system—implying thinner resumes and perhaps less appreciation for party etiquette in the top levels of leadership to come. Discussion Elite politics under the Xi Jinping administration has been anything but dull. Former and rising leaders within the Party have been convicted of corruption and the top echelons of power have been thoroughly reconstituted, all while Xi Jinping has doubled his portfolio, enshrined his name in the CCP charter, expanded his anti-corruption campaign to the state and public sector, and abolished any legal impediments to holding on to power indefinitely. How did Xi Jinping amass such unprecedented levels of personal power? What does this tell us about the future of the CCP under Xi Jinping and beyond? Is collective leadership dead, as some have suggested? Are we in store for a relapse into the strongman politics of the Mao era? 24 In this review, I have argued that Xi Jinping’s rise was facilitated by CCP elites, who in 2012 invested full authority into Xi’s office, even before he entered it. As in the case of Mahathir in Malaysia, we cannot ignore the possibility that Xi Jinping’s consolidation of power has helped stabilise a fractured party, at least for the short term. Further, I have shown that the inherent malleability of Chinese leadership norms and institutions has allowed Xi Jinping to expand his influence and promote his loyalists without overtly violating them. Indeed, the painstaking manner by which Xi Jinping has gone about securing his position and policy priorities arguably says less about his hunger for power than it does about his concern about upsetting the semblance of institutional legitimacy. Remember, ambiguous succession norms meant that Xi could have held on to power without amending the constitution, and he could have kept Wang Qishan without retiring him from the PBSC only to promote him to the vice-presidency three months later. Similarly, Xi’s anti-corruption agents within the CCDI could have imposed their control over procuratorates relatively easily, given overlapping leadership roles. Instead, Xi initiated a complex institutionalisation process for the NSC and subordinated provincial commissions, (37) backed by a new National Supervision Law that even went through 30 days of public notice and comment. (38) Curiously enough, it is believed that this institutionalisation effort, not a grand scheme, set off the constitutional revision process that opened the door to the removal of term 34. In 2014, Xi personally adopted Lankao as a pet project for poverty alleviation (Stromseth et al. 2017: 21). More recently, Xi inaugurated an ambitious campaign to wipe out poverty by 2020, see: Xu Lei, “Xi Urges Stepped-up Efforts to Eradicate Poverty by 2020,” China Daily, 23 February 2017, http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/china/2017-02/23/content_28310971.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). In 2016, Xi identified research as one of the core national weakness, urging more innovation in the physical and biological sciences. See: “The Future of Chinese Research.” Nature 534(7608): 435–435, 22 June 2016, www.nature.com/news/the-future-of-chinese-research-1.20123 (accessed on 15 November 2017). 35. It is worth noting that the air quality in Beijing has improved remarkably since November 2017, in large part thanks to the banning of coal burning in the city and surrounding provinces. 36. For a summary and links to the speech, see “7 Things You Need to Know About Xi Jinping’s Vision of a ‘New Era’ for China,” South China Morning Post, 18 October 2017, www.scmp.com/news/ china/policies-politics/article/2115858/key-points-xis-speech-chinas-communist-party-congress (accessed on 15 November 2017). Relatedly, Shih (2017) identifies an entire cohort of aerospace engineers taking on high-profile leadership positions across China, including the governorship of Zhejiang, Guangdong, Hunan, and the party secretary’s office in Heilongjiang. 37. “China to Set Up National Supervision Commission Next Year,” Xinhua, 30 October 2017, www.xinhuanet.com/english/2017-10/30/c_136713601.htm (accessed on 15 November 2017). 38. Charles Buckley, “In China, Fears That New Anticorruption Agency Will Be Above the Law,” The New York Times, 29 November 2017, www.nytimes.com/2017/11/29/world/asia/china-xi-jinping-anticorruption.html (accessed on 15 December 2017). china perspectives • No.2018/1-2 Dimitar D. Gueorguiev – Dictator’s Shadow: Chinese Elite Politics under Xi Jinping limits. (39) In short, it appears that Xi Jinping is both circumventing existing institutions and cautiously setting up a base, albeit a flimsy one, for new institutions to follow. To be clear, none of this is a silver lining for the future of democracy in China, but it does suggest that one-party rule has not been replaced by one-man rule. Indeed, Xi’s achievements in consolidating power are just as consequential for his willingness to one day retire as they are for his ability to remain in office indefinitely. Put differently, every incumbent leader requires some assurance that neither family, friends, nor legacies will become a target for retribution once he or she leaves office. This is especially true in regimes operating under weak rule of law and for incumbents who have made enemies during their tenure—both of which apply to China and Xi to the utmost degree. In this light, getting one’s name inscribed in the preamble of the party constitution is both a signal of supreme power and an insurance policy for peaceful retirement. Even though we cannot predict Xi’s intentions, we can observe the more subtle but systemic impact his power consolidation efforts have had on the Chinese political and administrative system. The impact is broad but concentrated in three areas. First, traditional divisions of power are being References blurred, with party and state functions becoming increasingly indistinguishable. Second, with regards to leadership selection and elite decision-making, we are seeing a departure from intra-party democracy in favour of more top-heavy modes of consultation. The third concerns future cohorts of power, where bottlenecks in the leadership pipeline reveal potential shortages in qualified contenders for future transitions. While these changes do not directly impinge on party norms, they pose challenges to the institutional structure of the party-state and its ability to govern. z Dimitar D. Gueorguiev is Assistant Professor of Political Science at the Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University. Syracuse University, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs, 100 Eggers Hall, Syracuse NY 13244-1020 (ddgueorg@syr.edu). Manuscript received on 2 April 2018. Accepted on 11 May 2018. 39. Charlotte Gao, “China Plans to Amend its Constitution,” op cit. HU, Wei. 2010. “Intraparty Democracy and Political Development.” In Keping Yu (ed.), Democracy and Rule of Law in China. Leiden: Brill. 97–122. ALBERTUS, Michael, and Victor MENALDO. 2012. “Dictators as Founding Fathers? The Role of Constitutions Under Autocracy.” Economics & Politics 24(3): 279–306. JI, You. 2002. “Profile: The Heir Apparent.” The China Journal 48(July). Contemporary China Centre, The Australian National University : 125–34. BOIX, Carles, and Milan W. SVOLIK. 2013. “The Foundations of Limited Authoritarian Government: Institutions, Commitment, and Power-Sharing in Dictatorships.” The Journal of Politics 75(2). Cambridge University Press: 300–316. LAMPTON, David M., and Kenneth G. LIEBERTHAL. 1992. “The ‘Fragmented Authoritarianism’ Model and Its Limitation.” In Kenneth G Lieberthal and David M Lampton (eds.), Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. 1–33. CAI, Hongbin, and Daniel TREISMAN. 2006. “Did Government Decentralization Cause China’s Economic Miracle?” World Politics 58(4). Cambridge University Press: 505–35. LI, Cheng. 2016. Chinese Politics in the Xi Jinping Era: Reassessing Collective Leadership. Washington: Brookings Institution Press. CHEUNG, Tai Ming. 2001. China’s Entrepreneurial Army. Oxford: Oxford University Press. LIN, Shangli. 2002. 党内民主: 中国共产党的理论与实践 (Dangnei minzhu: Zhongguo gongchang dang dangnei de lilun yu shilu, Inner Party democracy: Chinese Communist Party theory and practice). Shanghai: Shanghai Social Sciences Publishing. COX, Gary W. 2009. “Authoritarian Elections and Leadership Succession, 1975-2000.” Unpublished Manuscript. Toronto (Sept. 3-6): 1–22. politics.as.nyu.edu/docs/IO/6931/Cox_Paper.pdf (accessed on 1 December 2017) DEBS, Alexandre. 2016. “Living by the Sword and Dying by the Sword? Leadership Transitions in and out of Dictatorships.” International Studies Quarterly 60(1): 1–48. ESCRIBA-FOLCH, Abel. 2013. “Repression, Political Threats, and Survival under Autocracy.” International Political Science Review 34(5): 543–60. FEWSMITH, Joseph. 2013. “The 18th Party Congress: Testing the Limits of Institutionalization.” China Leadership Monitor 40(40): 1–9. GUEORGUIEV, Dimitar D., and Paul J. SCHULER. 2016. “Keeping Your Head Down: Public Profiles and Promotion Under Autocracy.” Journal of East Asian Studies 16(1): 87–116. HERZ, John H. 1952. “The Problem of Successorship in Dictatorial Régimes; A Study in Comparative Law and Institutions.” The Journal of Politics 14(1): 19–40. HSIAO, Russell. 2013. “Taiwan Work Leading Small Group under Xi Jinping - Jamestown.” China Brief 13(12): 10–13. HU, Angang. 2014. China’s Collective Presidency. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg. No.2018/1-2 • china perspectives MA, Xiao. 2016. “Term Limits And Authoritarian Power Sharing: Theory And Evidence From China.” Journal of East Asian Studies 16(1): 61–85. MANION, Melanie. 1993. Retirement of Revolutionaries in China: Public Policies, Social Norms, Private Interests. Princeton: Princeton University Press. MILLER, Alice L. 2008. “The CCP Central Committee’s Leading Small Groups | Hoover Institution.” China Leadership Monitor 26: 1–21. ———. 2016. “‘Core’ Leaders, ‘Authoritative Persons,’ and Reform Pushback.” China Leadership Monitor 50(50): 1–12. ———. 2017. “Xi Jinping And The Party’s ‘Guiding Ideology.’” China Leadership Monitor 54(54): 1–8. NATHAN, Andrew J. 1973. “A Factionalism Model for CCP Politics.” The China Quarterly 53(53): 34–66. ———. 2003. “China’s Changing of the Guard: Authoritarian Resilience.” Journal of Democracy 14(1): 6–17. NAUGHTON, Barry. 2017. “The General Secretary’s Extended Reach: Xi Jinping Combines Economics and Politics.” China Leadership Monitor 54. SHIH, Lea. 2017. “Aerospace Experts in China’s New Leadership.” China Policy Institute Analysis. cpianalysis.org/2017/10/25/aerospace-expertsin-chinas-new-leadership/ (accessed on 1 December 2017). 25 S p e ci a l feat ure SHIH, Victor. 2008. “‘Nauseating’ Displays of Loyalty: Monitoring the Factional Bargain through Ideological Campaigns in China.” The Journal of Politics 70(4): 1177. STREECK, Wolfgang, and Kathleen Ann. THELEN. 2005. Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ———. 2017. “Financial Instability in China | Mercator Institute for China Studies.” www.merics.org/en/microsite/china-monitor/financial-instability-china (accessed on 1 December 2017). STROMSETH, Jonathan R., Edmund J. MALESKY, and Dimitar D. GUEORGUIEV. 2017. China’s Governance Puzzle: Enabling Transparency and Participation in a Single-Party State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. SHIRK, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China. University of California Press. ———. 2002. “The Delayed Institutionalization of Leadership Politics.” In Jonathan Unger (ed.), The Nature of Chinese Politics: From Mao to Jiang. 297–312. SLATER, Dan. 2003. “Iron Cage in an Iron Fist: Authoritarian Institutions and the Personalization of Power in Malaysia.” Comparative Politics 36(1): 81–101. 26 SVOLIK, Milan W. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. WANG, Zhengxu, and Anastas VANGELI. 2016. “The Rules and Norms of Leadership Succession in China: From Deng Xiaoping to Xi Jinping and Beyond.” The China Journal 76(July): 24–40. XU, Chenggang. 2011. “The Fundamental Institutions of China’s Reforms and Development.” Journal of Economic Literature 49(4): 1076–1151. china perspectives • No.2018/1-2 Reproduced with permission of copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 https://doi.org/10.1007/s41111-018-0095-1 ORIGINAL ARTICLE The New, Green, Urbanization in China: Between Authoritarian Environmentalism and Decentralization Geoffrey C. Chen1 · Charles Lees2 Received: 6 July 2017 / Accepted: 4 February 2018 / Published online: 13 February 2018 © Fudan University and Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2018 Abstract Orthodox Western environmental practice and its associated discourse posits a positive causal link between levels of participation and effective environmental governance and regards participatory practices as a normatively desirable element in the building of a more sustainable society. However, recent discussions around theories of authoritarian environmentalism have challenged some basic assumptions of orthodox environmentalism. However, these discussions still lack sufficient discussion of real-world policy making and implementation and this article addresses that gap by exploring China’s policy of green urbanization, deemed a top priority by Chinese policy elites. We argue that the shifting strategies of governance associated with green urbanization are evidence of the emergence of a distinct paradigm of authoritarian environmentalism, characterized by a re-centralization of state power and a reduction of local autonomy, in environmental policy making in China. Keywords China · Environmentalism · Urbanization · Sustainable infrastructure * Geoffrey C. Chen chun‑fung.chen@xjtlu.edu.cn Charles Lees charles.lees@flinders.edu.au 1 Department of China Studies, Xi’an Jiaotong-Liverpool University, Suzhou, People’s Republic of China 2 College of Business, Government and Law, Flinders University, Bedford Park, Australia 13 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 213 1 Introduction The rise of Western environmentalism coincided with the growth of the anti-nuclear movement, the anti-war movement, and other emancipatory strands of state-social conflict in Western societies. What is now the orthodox environmental political discourse and practice emerged from this congruence and posits a positive causal link between participation and effective environmental governance as well as regarding participatory practices as a normatively desirable element in the building of a more sustainable society. However, recent discussions around theories of authoritarian environmentalism (Moore 2014; Beeson 2010, 2016) have challenged these assumptions at the same time as commentators have begun to focus on concerns about the potential chaos and security threats that may arise from acute environmental emergencies (Hartmann 2010; Detraz 2011; Nyman 2018). Given increasing doubts about the orthodox model of environmental governance (Blühdorn 2016; Howes et al. 2017), researchers’ discussions have turned to China as a possible alternative non-participatory model of environmental policy-making (Gilley 2012; Mol 2015). However, these discussions still lack sufficient discussion of actual real-world policy making and implementation. This article addresses that gap by exploring the policy of ‘green urbanization’, which has been deemed a top priority by Chinese policy elites, to understand authoritarian environmentalism as a possible alternative path to addressing China’s growing environmental emergency. The emergence of China as a major player in the politics of climate change has reawakened academic interest in non-democratic approaches to environmentalism as an alternative environmental policy model. By-and-large this scholarship has stopped short of outright advocacy of authoritarian environmentalism but it has breathed new life into the unresolved academic debate, dating back to the late 1970s, which pitted market liberalism against authoritarian command economies.1 These debates have re-emerged because of the limited progress made by orthodox Western approaches as well as China’s growing influence in global climate politics. Authoritarian environmentalism is the antithesis of emancipatory, decentralized environmentalism (Blühdorn 2011b, 4–5): tackling the environmental emergency using a non-participatory and top-down mode of governance. This approach is documented in Wainwright and Mann’s ‘Climate Mao’ (2013, 9–10), which conceives the Chinese state as an alternative to a neoliberal capitalist bloc led by the USA, and with the potential to ‘achieve political feats unimaginable in liberal democracy’. Similarly, Bigger (2012) argues that centralized state responses may be needed to address the fragmented state of global carbon governance. However, most of the new discussions around authoritarian environmentalism tend to portray China as a fixed, single entity and fail to understand the changing nature of environmental policy model(s) within China’s authoritarian system (Shen and Xie 2017). These debates have not 1 For further discussion and debate of authoritarian environmentalism, see, for instance, Heilbroner (1991), Doherty and De Geus (1996), Lafferty and Meadowcroft (1996), Midlarsky (1998), Barry and Wissenburg (2001), Shearman and Smith (2008), Humphrey (2009), Ophuls (1977, 2011), Blühdorn (2013, 23–29) and Chen (2016, 223–245). 13 214 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 taken into account the shift and evolution of the institutions and practices of policy making in China. By contrast, through our case study of green urbanization and the related policy initiatives, this article aims to understand the changing institutional configurations that have emerged over the last decade and, in doing so, enhance the empirical basis of what still remains primarily an intertextual and theoretically driven debate. Our research questions are as follows: 1. What are the institutions and policy instruments used by policy elites in China to implement their policy of ‘green urbanization’? 2. To what extent is the relevance and utility of the concept of Authoritarian Environmentalism capable of analyzing the mode of governance in this policy area? We use the concept of environmental authoritarianism as a theoretical lens to focus on these questions. Using the policy area of green urbanisation as a case study, we seek to grasp a more comprehensive understanding of the trajectory of China’s recent environmental policy development. The reason for selecting this policy area for analysis is that empirically, green urbanization has become a high salience political agenda for policy elites (Zhang 2015, 163–164; Xinhua News Agency 2017). The policy document Opinions on Accelerating the Construction of Ecological Civilization (Guanyu jiakuai tuijin shengtai wenming jianshe de yijian, 关于加快推进 生态文明建设的意见) co-introduced by the Party and the State Council, emphasizes the relationship between China’s environmental carrying capacity and the need for coordinated development. This indicates an intellectual shift towards a political economy that eschews high consumption, high emissions, high expansion and inefficient output, and which reflects Chinese policy elites’ awareness of the urgency of the climate issue. But in recognizing the urgency of the issue, we also see a new emphasis on environmental authoritarianism. The rest of the article is structured as follows. Next, we assess the debate around non-democratic approaches to environmental policy that have emerged in the recent literature. In section three, we focus on green urbanization in China, examining how China’s top-down approach has worked in practice. In particular, we look at the trade-off between notions of sustainability and equality in the policy design of green urbanization. We seek to identify the practical challenges and the policy shifts, as well as the thinking behind them that drove the implementation of green urbanization initiatives. In section four, we discuss our findings, and argue that the emerging strategies of governance associated with green urbanization can be characterised as part of the emerging paradigm of authoritarian environmentalism. This mode of authoritarian environmentalism not only diverges from the global consensus mode of environmental governance, but is in effect a new mode of policy making that emphasizes an explicitly result-oriented policy style that seeks to integrate environmental imperatives into economic policy planning. 13 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 215 1.1 The Paradigm of Participatory Environmental Governance Much has been written about the importance of widening civil society participation in environmental politics and policy. In the West, there is now an established orthodoxy that stretches from radical environmentalists, through mainstream politicians to business practitioners, in which actors at all levels of governance assumes a positive link between popular participation and environmental protection (Smith 2003; Hobson 2012). This orthodoxy was forged in the ongoing debate amongst academics, activists, and practitioners that dates back to the emergence of eco-politics in the 1960s and came to global prominence with the presentation of the Brundtland Report in 1987 (Blühdorn 2011a). Although the environmentalist orthodoxy emerged within the New Social Movements, from the mid-1980s onwards it became increasingly mainstream and unconstrained by social location (Bäckstrand and Lövbrand 2006). In its purest form, environmental actors have sought a radical, decentralized, and civil-society focused mode of organization that fundamentally challenged the capitalist materialism of the established economic system, advocating and seeking a new way of life (Scott 1990; Blühdorn 2009). This particular strand of environmentalism was closely associated with the anti-nuclear movements that were particularly active at the time (Kitschelt 1986) and the non-traditional techniques of mass mobilization associated with them achieved public and political attention and established the key issues in the wider public discourse in Western democracies (Price et al. 2014). Such movements, rooted in the tradition of emancipation, are explicitly opposed to hierarchical bureaucracy (Dobson 2007). In short, the Green politics that emerged through the new Social Movements saw defense of the environment and the extension of citizens’ autonomy as linked concepts with a close, positive relationship between them. However, from the 1980s onwards the radical edge of Green politics was subsumed into the more mainstream discourse of ‘sustainable development’, which has become the dominant framework for the discussion of international environmental politics (Hajer 1995; Huber 2000). Such an apparently depoliticized policy paradigm was in fact highly political in that its more formalized and structured model of stakeholder participation excluded the informal and often deliberately unstructured participation practices associated with New Social Movements (Blühdorn 2000a, b, 2013; Bäckstrand 2004, 696). This shift away from more radical practices of participation saw a shift from notions of open and deliberative practice to a more constrained contractual mode of cooperation between the public and private sectors (Joss 2010; Baker 2015). Although this more constrained notion of participation downplayed the radicalism of the New Social Movements it nevertheless still presented a challenge to existing practices in liberal democratic states. Not only does this conventional model of environmental governance contain nebulous strands of neo-liberal thinking but, in its emphasis on stakeholder participation policy paradigms, its narrative outsources the responsibilities of elected policy makers (who are supposed to be responsible for dealing with this vexing issue) to mass consumers (Blühdorn 2016) and eschews the state’s capacity to solve climate problems with large-scale global solutions. This paradigm embedded in the sustainable development agenda has, for 13 216 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 some, been considered an exhausted or even ‘failed paradigm’ (Bulkeley et al. 2013, 962–963; Blühdorn 2013, 260–264). As Blühdorn put it: This discourse presents consumer-citizens—rather than economic or political elites—as real center of power, demands that every individual contribute their bit, and suggests that the sum of individualized consumer choices and small scale behavior changes (for example, recycling household waste, not printing every email, using public transport more regularly, changing light bulbs) will deliver what neither the globalized economy nor the decapacitated state are able to achieve (2016, 269). In such paradigmatic decadence, in which the established model of environmental governance seems to have lost its effectiveness in dealing with climate urgency, Beeson echoed this argument, stating that ‘many democracies have great difficulty either overcoming powerful, entrenched domestic interests and generally following through on policy commitments, no matter how well intentioned they may be’ (Beeson 2017, 3). In this context, environmental authoritarianism offers new means to solve environmental problems on a large scale. In the next section, we focus on the empirical discussion of emerging non-democratic approaches to environmental policy making. 1.2 Authoritarian Environmentalism and the Case of China Authoritarian environmentalism dates back to the nineteenth century and the romantic movement’s critique of industrial revolution and the subsequent criticism in the twentieth Century of the anthropocentric nature of liberal democracy. In their own ways, Heilbroner (1974), Ophuls (1977), and Ophuls and Boyan (1992) all pointed to the inherent dilemma faced by contemporary market democratic states when confronted with the potential measures required to tackle the global environmental emergency. The core of this dilemma was what they saw as the inevitable tradeoff between the needs of the planet and individual rights; in this case the right to unlimitedly exploit the earth’s resources. These writers’ skepticism about the ability of democratic states to address the environmental emergency led to them being labelled proponents of authoritarian environmentalism (Blühdorn 2013). In particular, authoritarian environmentalism questioned the default principle of market liberalism that placed economic and political individualism as a priority value. For instance, Ophuls (1977, 223) pessimistically points out that ‘current political value and institutions are the products of the age of abnormal abundance now drawing to a close, so that solutions predicated on scarcity would necessarily conflict with them’. He believes that, to move toward a more stable environmentally benign society, ‘we must determine its basic principles and then put them into effect in a planned or a designed fashion’ (1977, 227). Authoritarian environmentalism generated a lively academic debate in the 1970s but, as Dryzek and Dunleavy (2009, 262–263) later observed, this academic discussion of authoritarian environmentalism ran into the sand simply because there had not yet been a substantial example of such a regime in the real world. 13 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 217 That being said, the criticism of political systems legitimized on the basis of a priori individualistic freedom and the pursuit of selfish consumerism has continued and many commentators have attempted to apply the principles of authoritarian environmentalism to the empirical world, building model nondemocratic approaches to climate policy. One of the more controversial works in this direction of enquiry is Shearman and Smith’s (2008) contribution that argues that liberal democracy itself may be an insurmountable obstacle to tackling the environmental emergency. For Shearman and Smith, the East Asian model of economic development, with its emphasis on technocratic management and a more collective ethos, may provide a more promising way forward than liberal democracy in general and its Anglo-Saxon variant in particular. Drawing on the earlier work of Ophuls (1977), Giddens (2011) also argues for a more active ‘interventionist’ role for the state and for the reversal of the neo-liberal deregulation of the past 30 years that has failed to mitigate or compensate for the externalities of economic activity (Giddens 2011, 96).2 This recent scholarship has reawakened interest in the potentialities of authoritarian environmentalism but as Blühdorn (2013, 24) points out, none of the models proposed succeed in illustrating exactly how and to what extent the institutional mechanisms of government ought to be arranged. Moreover, although academic debates accept the premise of the embedded tendency towards environmental and resource exploitation under market liberalism (Eckersley 2004, 87), authoritarian environmentalism is still tainted empirically by the experience of the totalitarian dead end and environmental catastrophe associated with the Soviet and East European model of planned economy in the twentieth century (Baker and Jehlička 1998; Foster 2015). At the same time, however, commentators continue to criticize the current environmental laggards in high-carbon-reliance countries like the US, Canada, and Australia. The emergence of the Chinese case in this conversation is in many ways unexpected, given that China is generally considered an environmental laggard and has been criticized by many researchers as a major cause of global warming (Schreurs 2011; Bulkeley and Newell 2015, 50). However, for some scholars, this criticism is not always justified. For instance, Beeson (2010) used the lively academic discussion around the rise of China as a means of raising the possibility of effective environmental governance under authoritarian rule. For Beeson, the rise of China is not only an unprecedented economic phenomenon in empirical terms, but he believes that it can even be conceived as an alternative environmental policy-making model due to urgent need to tackle the global environmental emergency. If one accepts that the environmental emergency has potential existential consequences, then it is possible to conceive of China’s interventionist state model as a template for rethinking and perhaps trying to reasonably replicate the same degree of state capacity to protect human civilization under the threat of global warming (Beeson 2010, 289). Beeson invited readers to take a different perspective to the normal critical position on China, and consider the fact that if the strong political control and one child policy had not existed in China, the sustainable carrying capacity of our planet could already have been exceeded. 2 And also to break the locked-in situation to resolve the obstacle resulted from the lobby groups’ long effort in denying the proposed climate policies in industrial states (Giddens 2011; Klein 2015). 13 218 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 Gilley (2012) attempts to extend this argument and build an environmental policy-making model that does not a priori emphasize the principle of participation. He defines authoritarian environmentalism as ‘a policy process that is dominated by a relatively autonomous central state, affording little or no role for social actors or their representatives’ (Gilley 2012, 288). Gilley points out that China’s active state intervention in environmental policy making can be explained by this theoretical framework, and the domination of scientific technocrats in managing and controlling the process conforms to the prototype of authoritarian environmentalism. However, Gilley remains doubtful that the model is even potentially superior to the orthodox Western model of participatory environmental policy making. In particular, Gilley points to the pathologies of administrative decentralization in China: the fact that managing and coordinating policy across such a large and geographically diverse territory often leads to a lack of coordination between central and local government that hinders the central state’s ability to implement effective environmental policies. Gilley concludes that while the policy elites have been able to generate high levels of environmental policy output, they have struggled to solve their long-term problems of implementation deficit (Gilley 2012, 298; also Economy 2010; Shapiro 2012). Eaton and Kostka (2014) also echo these accounts of implementation deficit and argue that one of the defining problems of environmental policy in Western democratic states, that of short-termism, also exists in China’s authoritarian system (see also Westra 1998, 86). These scholars argue that the Chinese Communist Party’s cadre turnover system means that key officials are often only in situ in a particular locality for 4 years. As a result, there are limits to the extent to which officials can cultivate local networks and this tends to scale up into an emphasis on quick but limited environmental gains. Furthermore, Eaton and Kostka (2017) posed an empirical challenge to an over-optimistic focus on environmental authoritarianism. In a recent article on the state-led protection of central enterprises, they indicated a long-standing environmental problem embedded in fragmented authoritarianism: central stateowned enterprises (SOEs) have long defied environmental laws, and the ‘National Champions’ rely on their superiority, which constrains the local governments’ capability to enforce environmental regulations. Under the protection of the central government (that is, the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission, the chief governing body of the central SOEs) and incentivised by industrial policies introduced by both central and local governments, they became chronic polluters, and non-compliance with local environmental regulations became the norm (Eaton and Kostka 2017, 694). After all, SOE managers seem to be motivated by appraisal systems that gauge their commercial performance rather than environmental compliance. In addition, the absence of stable institutional mechanisms for environmental governance in China has led many to believe that the state has long been part of the problem in terms of the shortcomings of environmental governance in China (Economy 2010, 110–117; Lo and Fryxell 2014), as Toke indicates: [T]he modes of environmental governance that are now dominant in China are slow to respond to these changes … At a local level there is a basic contradiction between officials that are incentivized for their ability to pursue economic development and the need to protect the environment (2017, 97). 13 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 219 This also means that there have been variegated responses within the localities in terms of implementing green development policy, depending on the degree of local autonomy (Lo and Fryxell 2014, 113). Such institutional contradictions inherently skew the outcomes of environmental governance and fuel the failure of the governance practices (Balula and Bina 2015, 119). From this perspective, it seems that the concept of authoritarian environmentalism is problematic in discussing empirical aspects in China, in which, given the still-insufficient discussion of actual real-world policy making, it remains ambiguous whether a potential new mode of governance can emerge. This is also reflected in the research report published by the Development Research Center of the State Council, which voiced concerns about China’s fragmented approach to green development policy (Lv 2015, 11–39). 2 A Top‑Down Mode of ‘New Urbanization’ For 4 years, New Urbanization (Xinxing chengzhenhua, 新型城镇化) has been an influential phrase noticeable in official media, reflecting its championing by the current Xi-Li administration. Urbanization in China has long been a policy issue for the current policy elites. However, this has become a more complex challenge in the years that preceded them taking power. Rapid environmental degradation, as well as the uneven distribution of resources accompanied by the change of land conversion (Gaubatz 1999; Ma 2002), has compelled the new leaders to advocate the introduction of new explicitly ‘green’ policies in the now well-established urbanization program.3 This new Green Urbanization marks a break from the past in that the design of the policy emphasizes the possibility of a cohesive, controlling but integrative institutionalization processes rather than encouraging the autonomy of third parties in the sector. In this sense, it is very different from the Western orthodoxy of sustainable development and reflects Chinese elites recognition of the need for top-level policy making to tackle China’s environmental crisis. 2.1 Crises and Unreconciled Remediation Official recognition of the environmental problems associated with China’s rapid development can be seen in the Chinese government’s 5-year guidelines (Hu and Liang 2011). The “Twelfth Five-Year Guideline” (Shi er wu guihua, 十二五规划), introduced in 2010 by the previous Hu-Wen administration, explicitly linked the issues of large-scale population mobility and environmental challenges and acknowledged the tension between the imperatives of economic growth and environmental 3 The bureaucratic system of the PRC has long been defined as a model of “Fragmented Authoritarianism”: the policy-making process in China, as argued by Lieberthal and Lampton (1988, 3) is “disjointed, protracted, and incremental”, which leads to competition for interests among provinces and key bureaucracies where policy coordination is difficult to reach. The extensive bargaining politics has therefore deeply involved in the process of policy implementation among territorial and hierarchical elites (Lampton 1987). 13 220 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 protection (China Development Research Foundation 2013; Darido et al. 2014). The document focused on the changes and challenges resulting from the early process of urbanization, particularly in eastern coastal areas. The “‘Twelfth Five-Year Guideline’ of National Population Development” (Guojia renkou fazhan “shi er wu” guihua, 国家人口发展“十二五”规划) referred to the associated problem of uneven population distribution and a large-scale floating population drawn from the countryside to the cities (State Council 2012). This problem, despite being acknowledged by Hu-Wen administration, has not been resolved due to the insufficient degree of social security and provision of public services for China’s increasingly expanding urban migrants. As Director of the National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) Xu Shaoshi observed: Over 200 million migrant workers and their families have been unable to enjoy equal access to basic public services of education, employment, health care, retirement, and affordable housing as urban residents. New structural dual contradictions within urban areas have emerged, which constrains the positive effect of urbanization that could have pushed forward domestic demand and structural upgrading of the economy. There are also potential risks to the security of the society (Xu 2013). The imbalanced distribution of the population and resources was accompanied by an overload on environmental resources. China’s rapid economic development was grounded on the unrestricted use of carbon energy, particularly coal, and resulted in an increasingly obvious negative environmental impact all over the country (Liu and Diamond 2005; OECD 2013). The unprecedented levels of environmental degradation were to a large extent linked to the business-as-usual energy structure. By 2010, China had become the world’s largest energy consumer and its energy consumption accounted for one-fifth of the world’s consumption (Leggett 2011). China’s poor environmental record also challenged the central state’s ability to maintain its high economic performance. Water scarcity, soil contamination, and air pollution not only created environmental overload (Liu and Diamond 2005; Kahn and Yardley 2007) but also began to exact a monetary cost, estimated to be around 13.5% of GDP in 2005 (Deutsche Welle 2015). In addition, a number of writers have indicated that ‘environmental mass incidents’ have increased dramatically year by year after the economic reform (Shapiro 2012, 131). As Wang stated: The number of legal petitioners has grown astronomically as pollution has worsened throughout the country and more than 40 new specialized courts or tribunals dedicated to hearing environmental lawsuits are now hearing cases, many of them brought by public interest plaintiffs including NGOs, private citizens, and environmental protection bureaus (2011; as cited in Shapiro 2012, 128). The overloading of environmental capacity is now firmly on the political agenda, attracting the criticism from a number of commentators and policy makers. Significant warnings raised by both domestic and international media seem to have pushed China’s political elites into a recognition that a crisis is emerging and that the current political-economic regime is unsustainable. 13 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 221 2.2 The Partial Return of Centralized Planning Official recognition of the extent of the crisis was made clear during the National People’s Congress and Chinese People’s Political Consultative Congress in 2015, in which Li Keqiang spoke bluntly at a press conference on the newly released government report, placing environmental protection and green urbanization at the very front of the tasks facing the State Council (BBC 2015; Xinhua News Agency 2015b). Key policy documents put forward in recent years have developed the notion of the ‘New Urbanization’. In 2014, the State Council released a lengthy policy document called “The National Guidelines of New Urbanization, 2014–2020” (Guojia xinxing chengzhenghua guihua, 2014–2020, 国家新型城镇化规划, 2014–2020), with a list of implementing strategies. In the document, policy makers highlighted urbanization as an important symbol of national modernization and set a new guiding ideology for urbanization. It stated, ‘[Chinese] Urbanization has been promoted against the backdrop of overpopulation, relative shortage of resources, fragile ecological environment, and uneven regional, urban, and rural development”. To achieve modernization, the authors of the “National Guidelines of New Urbanization, 2014–2020” listed several areas for development: from justice, urban and rural coordination, efficiency planning, environmental and ecological conservation, cultural development, and government guiding market mechanisms to the reconfirmation of the overall organization and the principle of control by the central government. Most notably, the document eschewed any references to Western orthodox principles of diversity and inclusivity in its proposed urbanization strategy. On the contrary, it proposed a strategy of ‘top level design’ (Dingceng sheji, 顶层设计), particularly in terms of the development of ecologically sustainable new towns (Xu 2013; State Council 2011; Noesselt 2017, 350).4 This new policy thinking, which incorporates the precautionary principle in tackling environmental problems at their source, emphasizes that in formulating policies, each department must accept higher level institutions, such as the State Council, to coordinate various departments in the governance system. For example, in energy governance, the State Council leads the Ministry of Environment, the National Development and Reform Commission, and provincial governments to tackle the long-running challenges (Liu et al. 2013, 145; Chen 2016, 200). The focus on top-down planning and steering was intended to “coordinately promote stable economic growth and structural optimization” (Xinhua News Agency 2015a). With its clear emphasis on the key role of the scientific and technocratic bureaucracy, the document rejects the orthodox template put forward by the World Bank and other international organizations, which prioritized an open and participatory process. By contrast, the Chinese document indicated a concerted move in the opposite direction, albeit for domestic reasons: to address the negative consequences of administrative decentralization (Shin 2013; Sorace and Hurst 2016). 4 These initiatives seem contrary to the joint research report “Urban China: Toward Efficient, Inclusive and Sustainable Urbanization”, coauthored by the State Department and the World Bank in 2014, which advocated an open and inclusive urbanization approach. 13 222 Chin. Polit. Sci. Rev. (2018) 3:212–231 Policy documents from recent years indicate that the Xi-Li administration’s approach to dealing with sensitive environmental issues is to look to enhance the technocratic bureaucracy’s steering capacity. One of the most significant of these documents was the revised Environmental Protection Act 2014, which came into force in 2015. The Act proposes a number of new institutional arrangements and policy instruments that are designed to allow the central state to further strengthen its ability to steer policy formulation and implementation.5 For instance, a new environmental pollution warning mechanism deploys the ‘precautionary principle’6 to allow closer monitoring of local government (Article 47) and also incentivize local officials to conform to and act in the interests of central government’s environmental objectives. The document also proposed a tougher approach to enforcing accountability by aligning performance to officials’ promotion prospects, a potential sanction that had previously been absent (Shapiro 2012). Other potential sanctions and rewards were now to be exercised by the Ministry of Environmental Protection, such as the right/power to detain the property of enterprises that have breached the environmental regulations and the right/power to sanction illegal enterprises (including sanctions in conjunction with other administrative departments such as financial and/or land use approval). The revised law also added a centralized regulatory intervention mechanism to address and sanction non-compliant behavior of both local government and enterprises, as well as to reduce rent-seeking behavior by business and government officials. One new measure introduced by central government since Xi Jinping came to power is the establishment of ‘environmental inspection teams’ (huanjing jiancha xiaozu, 环境监察小组). As with all similar inspection teams (xunshizu, 巡视组) dispatched by the Party-State, environmental inspection teams contain retired ministry officials and officials from the Organization Department of the Chinese Communist Party who carry out tours of provincial administrative units’ environmental monitoring facilities. This top-down mode of inspection was strongly advocated and subsequently institutionalized in 2015 by the Deepening Reform Leadership Small Group (Naughton 2017, 5–6). Xi Jinping’s 2017 report to the nineteenth party congress proposed more formal mechanisms of centralized monitoring by establishing natural resources asset management and natural ecological regulatory ...
Purchase answer to see full attachment
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following Studypool's honor code & terms of service.

Explanation & Answer

Attached.

Running header: AUTHORITARIAN ENVIRONMENTALISM

AUTHORITARIAN ENVIRONMENTALISM
Student name:
Affiliated Institution:
Professor name:
Date:

AUTHORITARIAN ENVIRONMENTALISM

2

1.
How has Xi Jinping changed or manipulated the political system for his ends,
according to Gueorguiev?
President Xi Jinping has been most recently described as the most powerful leader since
the reign of Chairman Mao. He has employed different constitutional tactics to ensure that his
reign is supreme and has longevity. This is made possible by the inception of ambiguous
leadership institutions and elite complicity which has in a great way facilitated Xi’s power
consolidation. President Xi’s reign has been marked with departure from collective decision
making and making everything classified. This has discouraged the voices of reason in the
community from participating in decision making leaving Xi and his loyalists to make all
decisions. Xi has also waged an anti-corruption war in the country which he uses to justify the
installation of loyalists into positions of leadership. This is despite their age. This prohibits
grooming of the upcoming leaders which thins out the herd of successors. Over the past five
years, Xi has brought back the title of a “core leader,” cemented his ideological “thought” into
the constitution of the Chinese Communist Party and changed the constitution of the people’s
republic of China to remove term limits for the office of the president.
Xi has consolidated power by ensuring that there are no boundaries between politics, the
economy, and military activities. He does this by heading almost all the essential organs of the
nation. He is the head of 12 major institutions in the nation whi...


Anonymous
Great study resource, helped me a lot.

Studypool
4.7
Trustpilot
4.5
Sitejabber
4.4

Similar Content

Related Tags