critical evaluation

Anonymous
timer Asked: May 18th, 2019
account_balance_wallet $40

Question Description

Purpose: In this assignment, you will write a critical evaluation of the paper, “Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning In” by Exley et al (2019). You will analyze the paper and relate it to the experiences of people around you.

Steps:

  1. Read “Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning In”. Also read the Harvard Business Review summary of the paper here: https://hbr.org/2016/04/women- who-dont-negotiate-their-salaries-might-have-a-good-reason
  2. Critically evaluate the paper. This should involve each of the following. • In one or two paragraphs, briefly summarize the paper’s primary conclusion and the evidence they use to support their hypothesis. • Assess whether the paper’s empirical results do and do not support the author’s findings. What other potential explanations are there for the empirical patterns uncovered by the authors? • Assess whether the paper’s empirical results are externally valid. That is, to what extent can the empirical results of this paper be extrapolated to other settings? Explain your reasoning.

3.

4. Revise your draft.

  • Check: does each paragraph express one clear idea? Do you tell the reader what that idea is in a topic sentence?
  • To make sure that your writing is concise and clear, take a word count of each paragraph, and then cut 10% of the words.
  • Print your draft and read it out loud to help you identify spots where the language or ideas could be clearer.


Unformatted Attachment Preview

Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning-in Christine L. Exley, Muriel Niederle, and Lise Vesterlund ∗ October 17, 2018 Abstract Women’s reluctance to negotiate is often used to explain the gender wage gap, popularizing the push for women to “lean-in” and negotiate more. Examining an environment where women achieve positive profits when they choose to negotiate, we find that increased negotiations are not helpful. Women know when to ask: they enter negotiations resulting in positive profits and avoid negotiations resulting in negative profits. While the findings are similar for men, we find no evidence that men are more adept than women at knowing when to ask. Thus, our results caution against a greater push for women to negotiate. Keywords: gender; negotiations; leaning-in; selection 1 Introduction Should women negotiate their salaries more often? According to 75% of adults recently surveyed in the United States, the answer is simply yes.1 The belief that women should negotiate more is also reflected in the popular push for women to “lean-in” (Sandberg, 2013).2 Indeed, concern that women’s negotiation decisions contribute to the wage gap has motivated a large academic literature on what factors influence women’s negotiation decisions. For instance, building on past research (e.g., Babcock and Laschever, 2003), the literature on negotiation decisions ∗ Exley: Harvard Business School, clexley@hbs.edu; Niederle: Stanford University and NBER, niederle@stanford.edu; Vesterlund: University of Pittsburgh and NBER, vester@pitt.edu 1 Results from a Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 202) that asked “Do you think women should negotiate their salaries more often?” (no/yes). Another Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 201) that instead asked about men found that 54% responded yes to men negotiating more often. 2 While we focus on whether women should “lean-in” to negotiate more, related questions include whether women should lean-in by entering competitions more (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007, 2011), entering challenging tasks more (Niederle and Yestrumskas, 2008), guessing more (Baldiga, 2014), or contributing their ideas more (Coffman, 2014). includes recent observational evidence (Card, Cardoso and Kline, 2016), laboratory studies (Dittrich, Knabe and Leipold, 2014) and field experiments (Leibbrandt and List, 2015).3 The push for women to negotiate more, however, is often accompanied by a caution: 66% of adults recently surveyed in the United States report that women may lose from negotiating their salaries more.4 The potential loss from negotiations can take many forms. Negotiations may instill immediate costs in the form of opportunity costs of time or disutility from negotiations themselves. They may give rise to future costs in the form of backlash (Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Tinsley et al., 2009; Amanatullah and Morris, 2010; Amanatullah and Tinsley, 2013), damage to one’s reputation, or decreased chances of future negotiations being successful.5 Further negotiation costs may be particularly large in the case of a negotiation impasse. For example, failure to reach an agreement may reduce returns to future collaboration, result in legal costs, or, in extreme cases, prompt the retraction of job offers or previous agreements.6 The low entry into negotiation by women and the possibility of both gains and losses raise the question of whether women financially benefit from negotiating more. While vast, the literature on gender and negotiation does not answer this question. The finding that women who negotiate benefit from doing so does not imply that all women benefit from negotiating more. Selection may play a role. To determine whether increased negotiations are financially beneficial to women, this paper provides the first comparison of outcomes from a setting where individuals choose whether to negotiate to the counterfactual outcomes from a setting where individuals always negotiate. 3 For additional evidence, see Stuhlmacher and Walters (1999); Bowles and McGinn (2008); Eckel, de Oliveira and Grossman (2008); Bowles (2013); Azmat and Petrongolo (2014); Mazei et al. (2015); Bohnet (2016). Note that a number of factors influence gender differences in negotiation outcomes such as the sex of negotiating partners (Eckel and Grossman, 2001; Solnick, 2001; Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Sutter et al., 2009; Hernandez-Arenaz and Iriberri, 2018b), the activation of stereotypes (Kray, Thompson and Galinsky, 2001; Kray, Galinsky and Thompson, 2002), the availability of information on what others do or what is recommended (Bowles, Babcock and McGinn, 2005; Rigdon, 2012), the beneficiaries of the negotiation (Bowles, Babcock and McGinn, 2005), the extent to which the possibility for a negotiation is known (Small et al., 2007; Leibbrandt and List, 2015), the framing of the situation as a negotiation or an ask (Small et al., 2007), the cultural context of the negotiations (Andersen et al., 2013), the relative positional power in a negotiation (Andersen et al., 2013; Dittrich, Knabe and Leipold, 2014; Greenberg and Petrie, 2015), the communication strategies or mode (Bowles and Babcock, 2013; Bowles, 2013; Greenberg and Petrie, 2015), the ability to signal valuations or experience (Castillo et al., 2013; Busse, Israeli and Zettelmeyer, 2016), age (Chandra, Gulati and Sallee, 2017), and the existence of sharing norms (Hernandez-Arenaz and Iriberri, 2018a). Gender differences in preferences, such as risk aversion or fairness concerns, may also contribute to differences in negotiation outcomes. For survey papers on gender differences in such preferences, see Croson and Gneezy (2009), Bertrand (2011) and Niederle (2016). 4 Results from a Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 200) that asked “Do you think women can lose from negotiating their salaries more often?” (no/yes/ sometimes yes, other times no). Another Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 203), that instead asked about men, found that 63% responded “yes” or “sometimes yes, other times no.” 5 For explanations why women who negotiate are disliked, see e.g. http://www.today.com/money/womenasking-raise-damned-if-you-do-if-you-dont-2D11658374. 6 Examples of such extreme cases include a woman’s job offer as an assistant professor being retracted after trying to negotiate (http://www.newyorker.com/science/maria-konnikova/lean-out-the-dangersfor-women-who-negotiate) and a consultant who was fired after asking for a pay raise for a promotion (http://www.cbsnews.com/news/can-you-be-fired-for-asking-for-a-raise). 2 We conduct laboratory experiments that abstract away from factors that are known to induce gender differences in more complex negotiations. This abstraction allows us to study the negotiation decisions themselves. Participants are anonymous to mitigate fear of discrimination or backlash. To limit ambiguity, they encounter explicit negotiation opportunities and decisions. Participants are informed of what they bring to the table to ease concerns related to lacking confidence. They are informed of their outside options to make the potential loss of a negotiation clear. Whether participants can avoid negotiations, however, varies across our two treatments. Participants in our Choice treatment can choose to avoid a negotiation opportunity and instead receive an outside option. By contrast, participants in our Always treatment must always enter negotiations. When women choose to enter negotiations in the Choice treatment, they largely gain from doing so. We nonetheless replicate the common finding that women frequently avoid negotiations. While this has been seen as evidence that an increase in negotiations will secure improvements for women, we find, from the counterfactual of women always negotiating, that there are no gains from increased negotiations. When given a choice, women already enter negotiation opportunities that result in gains. They only avoid negotiation opportunities that would have otherwise resulted in losses. Increased negotiations are not helpful to women; in fact, they are harmful. Forcing women to negotiate hurts them. In considering the outcomes among men, we further show that increased negotiations do not result in relatively better outcomes for women than they do for men. Examining the selection into negotiations provides a similar takeaway. When comparing the financial outcomes from “self-selected” negotiations that workers choose to enter in the Choice treatment to those from “non-self-selected” negotiations in the Always treatment, it is clear that women know when to ask and men are not more adept at knowing when to ask than women are. Put differently, our paper cautions against targeting lean-in advice towards women. This caution is strengthened by findings from two additional experiments. First, while the initial laboratory experiment was conducted at Stanford University with 292 participants, we replicate our initial study at the University of Pittsburgh using a larger sample of 398 participants. Second, we conduct an online experiment that provides incentive compatible evidence of a greater paternalistic demand to eliminate a worker’s ability to avoid a negotiation if the worker is female rather than male. Our paper first reports on our initial laboratory experiment conducted at Stanford University: with the corresponding details for the design in Section 2, the data in Section 3, and the results in Section 4. In Section 5, we discuss our replication conducted at University of Pittsburgh. In Section 6, we present the evidence on the third-party demand for increased negotiations from an online experiment. In Section 7, we discuss extensions and limitations of our results as well as potential implications on recommendations for helping women to negotiate. 3 2 Design We create a negotiation environment, using Ztree (Fischbacher, 2007), where participants can compose free-form arguments for their point of view and can separately generate official proposals which the opposing side can accept at any time. Participants are evenly split between firms and workers at the beginning of sessions of each treatment. They remain in their randomly assigned role throughout the session. Participants face two blocks of five negotiation opportunities. Each block is preceded by one performance round that determines the individual contribution a participant brings to each of the subsequent five negotiation opportunities. For each negotiation opportunity, participants are randomly matched into worker-firm pairs with joint revenues equal to the sum of the worker contribution and the firm contribution. The computer generates a random suggested wage that correlates with the worker contribution. Workers in the Choice treatment can decide to enter into a negotiation with the firm or to forgo the negotiation by accepting the suggested wage. Workers in the Always treatment enter negotiations while still observing the suggested wage. All negotiations concern the share of joint revenue the worker receives as a wage. Negotiations that fail to reach an agreement result in the suggested wage being implemented along with a five-dollar impasse penalty for both the worker and the firm. Appendix B contains the instructions given to participants. These instructions include information on workers and firms as well as screenshots of how negotiations take place. Instructions are read out loud to guarantee that the structure of the experiment is common information. Before turning to the description and motivation for each design element, we note that our design purposefully limits three channels that have been shown to generate gender differences in negotiations.7 First, individuals know their individual contributions to prevent gender differences in confidence about what one brings to the table (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007; Mobius et al., 2014). Second, negotiations are anonymous to reduce potential fears of backlash among women in particular (Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Tinsley et al., 2009; Amanatullah and Morris, 2010; Amanatullah and Tinsley, 2013). Third, the negotiation opportunity is explicit to reduce the potential for gender differences arising from uncertainty about whether a negotiation is possible (Small et al., 2007; Leibbrandt and List, 2015). Individual Contributions and Joint Revenue Participants perform a five-minute real-effort task at the beginning of each of the two negotiation blocks. Their performance determines their individual contribution for the subsequent five rounds of negotiation opportunities in that block. A worker’s contribution is $20, $15 or $10, depending on whether the worker’s performance is the highest, second highest or third highest when compared to two other randomly selected workers. A firm’s contribution is $25 or $20, 7 To examine whether increased negotiations are beneficial to women, we sought to design an environment where negotiations are generally profitable for women. Showing that increased negotiations are not helpful to women in an environment where women rarely do well in negotiations would be less informative. 4 depending on whether the firm’s performance is the highest or second highest performance when compared to one other randomly selected firm. Any performance ties are broken randomly, and all participants are informed that this process determines contributions. In the first block, the real-effort task is to calculate the sum of five two-digit numbers. In the second block, the task is to count the number of zeros in a table with ten rows and five columns of zeros and ones (i.e., one row may appear like “00101”). Since participants’ relative performances may vary across the two tasks, their individual contributions may vary across the two blocks. After learning their individual contributions for a block, participants face five rounds of negotiation opportunities. In each round, a firm and a worker are randomly paired, and the joint revenue is the sum of the worker and firm contributions. By making contribution levels not depend linearly on performances and instead imply a set of contribution levels, we ensure that variation in individual contribution levels can be easily explained. The variance in individual contribution levels also generates multiple focal points of the negotiation. In addition to arguing for “equal splits” where the joint revenue is split 50-50, individuals may argue for “equity splits” where the joint revenue is split proportionally according to their individual contributions. The potential insistence on equity splits may result from individuals feeling entitled to their contribution and seeing it as the relevant reference point, particularly since individual performances determine individual contribution levels (Konow, 2000).8 On the other hand, the highest contribution level of the worker equals the lowest contribution level of the firm, which may help workers justify requests that exceed their individual contribution levels.9 The firm is always informed of the worker contribution. Whether the worker is informed of the firm contribution depends on the study version. In a common information version, the worker is informed of the firm contribution. In a private information version, the worker is not informed of the firm contribution. This variation in information is motivated by the finding that women often fare worse in negotiations that involve more ambiguity (see Bowles and McGinn (2008) and Mazei et al. (2015) for reviews, or Leibbrandt and List (2015) for recent evidence). However, perhaps given the anonymity and explicit choice to negotiate in our setting, this variation in knowledge does not produce significantly different results.10 Our analysis will therefore not focus on this variation and instead includes it as a control where relevant. 8 Feeling entitled may influence individuals’ decisions as shown in Hoffman et al. (1994) and discussed more broadly in Engel (2011). Since much of this work examines dictator games, it is interesting to note that Demiral and Mollerstrom (2018) do not find evidence for an entitlement effect in ultimatum games. 9 See Konow, Saijo and Akai (2016) for a discussion on “equality” and “equity” principles of fairness. The equity principle may also be referred to as being Libertarian (Almås et al., 2010). For earlier work showing that multiple reference points and fairness principles can result in diverse negotiation outcomes see also Roth and Murnighan (1982). 10 For instance, workers enter negotiations 72% of the time when there is private information and 69% of the time when there is common information. We fail to reject the equality of the entrance rates (p = 0.36) and the equality of the average profit from negotiations of $1.31 vs $1.23 conditional on negotiations (p = 0.74). 5 Suggested Wage and Potential Payoffs In the Choice treatment, a worker can choose to avoid negotiations by accepting a “suggested wage.” The suggested wage for a worker equals the worker contribution plus a bonus that in each round is randomly and uniformly drawn from the set -4, -2, 0, 2. While workers know that the suggested wage is random, they do not know the details of the process. However, knowing their own contribution levels, workers can determine the extent to which suggested wages differ from their own contributions. If a worker accepts a suggested wage, the firm receives the joint revenue minus the suggested wage. If a worker instead enters a negotiation in the Choice treatment, or when a worker always negotiates in the Always treatment, two payoff scenarios are possible. When an agreement is reached, the worker receives the agreed upon wage and the firm receives the remainder of the joint revenue. When an agreement is not reached, the suggested wage is implemented along with a five-dollar impasse penalty for both the worker and firm. That is, the worker receives the suggested wage minus five dollars, and the firm receives the joint revenue minus the suggested wage minus five dollars. Table 1 summarizes these potential payoffs. One round from each block is randomly selected for payment. Table 1: Worker Payoffs (W) and Firm Payoffs (F) No Negotiation Negotiation Agreement Negotiation Impasse Choice treatment Always Treatment W = suggested wage N/A F = joint revenue - suggested wage W = agreed upon wage F = joint revenue - agreed upon wage W = suggested wage - $5 F = joint revenue - suggested wage - $5 W indicates the payoff for the worker, and F indicates the payoff for the firm. In the Choice treatment, a worker may decide to accept the suggested wage and thus not enter a negotiation. The resulting payoffs are shown in the No Negotiation row. Alternatively, a worker may choose to reject the suggested wage and enter a negotiation. Payoffs when an agreement is reached are shown in the Negotiation Agreement row, while payoffs when an agreement in not reached are shown in the Negotiation Impasse row. In the Always treatment, workers always enter negotiations so only these latter two payoffs are relevant. The suggested wage serves as a focal point for negotiations, as agreed upon wages should fall within $5 of the suggested wage. Outside of the resulting $10 range for a given suggested wage, a payoff dominant strategy – for either the worker or the firm – would instead involve a negotiation impasse which implements the suggested wage with the $5 penalty. Assuming risk neutrality, the suggested wage indeed corresponds to the symmetric Nash Bargaining Solution since it results – with a symmetric $5 penalty – from an impasse. There are thus three potential focal points for negotiations: the equal split, the equity split, and the symmetric Nash Bargaining Solution (i.e., implementing the suggested wage). 6 In varying the extent to which ...
Purchase answer to see full attachment

Tutor Answer

JackyAbed
School: University of Virginia

Hey buddy here is the answer.

Running Head: CRITICAL EVALUATION

1

Lean in
Institutional Affiliation
Date
19th May 2019

CRITICAL EVALUATION

2

Lean in has mostly been pushed for women more than it is pushed for men. Due to the
wage inequality where women are generally paid less than men, there has been a widespread
belief that women should negotiate more for their wages. In this effect, lean in had been
recommended mostly for women than men. While this is the case, it is important to evaluate
whether lean in is beneficial to women or whether it brings about negative outcomes as opposed
to positive outcomes. For this matter, we evaluate the research on both women and men in a
Choice negotiation and Always negotiation scenario to determine the outcomes. The study hopes
to evaluate whether lean in is more beneficial to women than men, whether it brings more
negative outcomes or positive outcomes in both genders and in comparison as well.
The study finds that in general increased negotiation are not beneficial to either women or
men. In this sense, the study, therefore, establishes that there are no increased benefits in general
from increased negotiations be it through Choice negotiation or Always negotiations....

flag Report DMCA
Review

Anonymous
Top quality work from this guy! I'll be back!

Similar Questions
Related Tags

Brown University





1271 Tutors

California Institute of Technology




2131 Tutors

Carnegie Mellon University




982 Tutors

Columbia University





1256 Tutors

Dartmouth University





2113 Tutors

Emory University





2279 Tutors

Harvard University





599 Tutors

Massachusetts Institute of Technology



2319 Tutors

New York University





1645 Tutors

Notre Dam University





1911 Tutors

Oklahoma University





2122 Tutors

Pennsylvania State University





932 Tutors

Princeton University





1211 Tutors

Stanford University





983 Tutors

University of California





1282 Tutors

Oxford University





123 Tutors

Yale University





2325 Tutors