Evaluation Of Cost Of Leaning in Analysis

User Generated

UrlJbeyq

Writing

Description

Prompt is attached, word limit is 900.

Steps:

1. Read “Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning In”. Also read the Harvard

Business Review summary of the paper here: https://hbr.org/2016/04/women- who-dont-negotiate-their-salaries-might-have-a-good-reason 2. Critically evaluate the paper. This should involve each of the following.

• In one or two paragraphs, briefly summarize the paper’s primary conclusion and the evidence they use to support their hypothesis.

• Assess whether the paper’s empirical results do and do not support the author’s findings. What other potential explanations are there for the empirical patterns uncovered by the authors?

• Assess whether the paper’s empirical results are externally valid. That is, to what extent can the empirical results of this paper be extrapolated to other settings? Explain your reasoning. 3. Talk to 2 people who have worked for at least 5 years—people you know well enough to have a conversation about wage negotiations. Discuss with each of these people if they have negotiated their wages, and why or why not; if applicable, discuss also their experiences negotiating their wages. Do their experiences match the claims and assumptions made in the paper? How and/or how not? What does this suggest about the paper’s methodology, conclusions, and/or assumptions? Choose the most interesting points of critique or analysis of the paper that emerge from this to present in the final paragraph of your paper.

4. Revise your draft.

• Check: does each paragraph express one clear idea? Do you tell the reader what that idea is in a topic sentence?

• To make sure that your writing is concise and clear, take a word count of each paragraph, and then cut 10% of the words.

• Print your draft and read it out loud to help you identify spots where the language or ideas could be clearer.

Unformatted Attachment Preview

Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning-in Christine L. Exley, Muriel Niederle, and Lise Vesterlund ∗ October 17, 2018 Abstract Women’s reluctance to negotiate is often used to explain the gender wage gap, popularizing the push for women to “lean-in” and negotiate more. Examining an environment where women achieve positive profits when they choose to negotiate, we find that increased negotiations are not helpful. Women know when to ask: they enter negotiations resulting in positive profits and avoid negotiations resulting in negative profits. While the findings are similar for men, we find no evidence that men are more adept than women at knowing when to ask. Thus, our results caution against a greater push for women to negotiate. Keywords: gender; negotiations; leaning-in; selection 1 Introduction Should women negotiate their salaries more often? According to 75% of adults recently surveyed in the United States, the answer is simply yes.1 The belief that women should negotiate more is also reflected in the popular push for women to “lean-in” (Sandberg, 2013).2 Indeed, concern that women’s negotiation decisions contribute to the wage gap has motivated a large academic literature on what factors influence women’s negotiation decisions. For instance, building on past research (e.g., Babcock and Laschever, 2003), the literature on negotiation decisions ∗ Exley: Harvard Business School, clexley@hbs.edu; Niederle: Stanford University and NBER, niederle@stanford.edu; Vesterlund: University of Pittsburgh and NBER, vester@pitt.edu 1 Results from a Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 202) that asked “Do you think women should negotiate their salaries more often?” (no/yes). Another Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 201) that instead asked about men found that 54% responded yes to men negotiating more often. 2 While we focus on whether women should “lean-in” to negotiate more, related questions include whether women should lean-in by entering competitions more (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007, 2011), entering challenging tasks more (Niederle and Yestrumskas, 2008), guessing more (Baldiga, 2014), or contributing their ideas more (Coffman, 2014). includes recent observational evidence (Card, Cardoso and Kline, 2016), laboratory studies (Dittrich, Knabe and Leipold, 2014) and field experiments (Leibbrandt and List, 2015).3 The push for women to negotiate more, however, is often accompanied by a caution: 66% of adults recently surveyed in the United States report that women may lose from negotiating their salaries more.4 The potential loss from negotiations can take many forms. Negotiations may instill immediate costs in the form of opportunity costs of time or disutility from negotiations themselves. They may give rise to future costs in the form of backlash (Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Tinsley et al., 2009; Amanatullah and Morris, 2010; Amanatullah and Tinsley, 2013), damage to one’s reputation, or decreased chances of future negotiations being successful.5 Further negotiation costs may be particularly large in the case of a negotiation impasse. For example, failure to reach an agreement may reduce returns to future collaboration, result in legal costs, or, in extreme cases, prompt the retraction of job offers or previous agreements.6 The low entry into negotiation by women and the possibility of both gains and losses raise the question of whether women financially benefit from negotiating more. While vast, the literature on gender and negotiation does not answer this question. The finding that women who negotiate benefit from doing so does not imply that all women benefit from negotiating more. Selection may play a role. To determine whether increased negotiations are financially beneficial to women, this paper provides the first comparison of outcomes from a setting where individuals choose whether to negotiate to the counterfactual outcomes from a setting where individuals always negotiate. 3 For additional evidence, see Stuhlmacher and Walters (1999); Bowles and McGinn (2008); Eckel, de Oliveira and Grossman (2008); Bowles (2013); Azmat and Petrongolo (2014); Mazei et al. (2015); Bohnet (2016). Note that a number of factors influence gender differences in negotiation outcomes such as the sex of negotiating partners (Eckel and Grossman, 2001; Solnick, 2001; Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Sutter et al., 2009; Hernandez-Arenaz and Iriberri, 2018b), the activation of stereotypes (Kray, Thompson and Galinsky, 2001; Kray, Galinsky and Thompson, 2002), the availability of information on what others do or what is recommended (Bowles, Babcock and McGinn, 2005; Rigdon, 2012), the beneficiaries of the negotiation (Bowles, Babcock and McGinn, 2005), the extent to which the possibility for a negotiation is known (Small et al., 2007; Leibbrandt and List, 2015), the framing of the situation as a negotiation or an ask (Small et al., 2007), the cultural context of the negotiations (Andersen et al., 2013), the relative positional power in a negotiation (Andersen et al., 2013; Dittrich, Knabe and Leipold, 2014; Greenberg and Petrie, 2015), the communication strategies or mode (Bowles and Babcock, 2013; Bowles, 2013; Greenberg and Petrie, 2015), the ability to signal valuations or experience (Castillo et al., 2013; Busse, Israeli and Zettelmeyer, 2016), age (Chandra, Gulati and Sallee, 2017), and the existence of sharing norms (Hernandez-Arenaz and Iriberri, 2018a). Gender differences in preferences, such as risk aversion or fairness concerns, may also contribute to differences in negotiation outcomes. For survey papers on gender differences in such preferences, see Croson and Gneezy (2009), Bertrand (2011) and Niederle (2016). 4 Results from a Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 200) that asked “Do you think women can lose from negotiating their salaries more often?” (no/yes/ sometimes yes, other times no). Another Google Consumer Survey (February 2017, n = 203), that instead asked about men, found that 63% responded “yes” or “sometimes yes, other times no.” 5 For explanations why women who negotiate are disliked, see e.g. http://www.today.com/money/womenasking-raise-damned-if-you-do-if-you-dont-2D11658374. 6 Examples of such extreme cases include a woman’s job offer as an assistant professor being retracted after trying to negotiate (http://www.newyorker.com/science/maria-konnikova/lean-out-the-dangersfor-women-who-negotiate) and a consultant who was fired after asking for a pay raise for a promotion (http://www.cbsnews.com/news/can-you-be-fired-for-asking-for-a-raise). 2 We conduct laboratory experiments that abstract away from factors that are known to induce gender differences in more complex negotiations. This abstraction allows us to study the negotiation decisions themselves. Participants are anonymous to mitigate fear of discrimination or backlash. To limit ambiguity, they encounter explicit negotiation opportunities and decisions. Participants are informed of what they bring to the table to ease concerns related to lacking confidence. They are informed of their outside options to make the potential loss of a negotiation clear. Whether participants can avoid negotiations, however, varies across our two treatments. Participants in our Choice treatment can choose to avoid a negotiation opportunity and instead receive an outside option. By contrast, participants in our Always treatment must always enter negotiations. When women choose to enter negotiations in the Choice treatment, they largely gain from doing so. We nonetheless replicate the common finding that women frequently avoid negotiations. While this has been seen as evidence that an increase in negotiations will secure improvements for women, we find, from the counterfactual of women always negotiating, that there are no gains from increased negotiations. When given a choice, women already enter negotiation opportunities that result in gains. They only avoid negotiation opportunities that would have otherwise resulted in losses. Increased negotiations are not helpful to women; in fact, they are harmful. Forcing women to negotiate hurts them. In considering the outcomes among men, we further show that increased negotiations do not result in relatively better outcomes for women than they do for men. Examining the selection into negotiations provides a similar takeaway. When comparing the financial outcomes from “self-selected” negotiations that workers choose to enter in the Choice treatment to those from “non-self-selected” negotiations in the Always treatment, it is clear that women know when to ask and men are not more adept at knowing when to ask than women are. Put differently, our paper cautions against targeting lean-in advice towards women. This caution is strengthened by findings from two additional experiments. First, while the initial laboratory experiment was conducted at Stanford University with 292 participants, we replicate our initial study at the University of Pittsburgh using a larger sample of 398 participants. Second, we conduct an online experiment that provides incentive compatible evidence of a greater paternalistic demand to eliminate a worker’s ability to avoid a negotiation if the worker is female rather than male. Our paper first reports on our initial laboratory experiment conducted at Stanford University: with the corresponding details for the design in Section 2, the data in Section 3, and the results in Section 4. In Section 5, we discuss our replication conducted at University of Pittsburgh. In Section 6, we present the evidence on the third-party demand for increased negotiations from an online experiment. In Section 7, we discuss extensions and limitations of our results as well as potential implications on recommendations for helping women to negotiate. 3 2 Design We create a negotiation environment, using Ztree (Fischbacher, 2007), where participants can compose free-form arguments for their point of view and can separately generate official proposals which the opposing side can accept at any time. Participants are evenly split between firms and workers at the beginning of sessions of each treatment. They remain in their randomly assigned role throughout the session. Participants face two blocks of five negotiation opportunities. Each block is preceded by one performance round that determines the individual contribution a participant brings to each of the subsequent five negotiation opportunities. For each negotiation opportunity, participants are randomly matched into worker-firm pairs with joint revenues equal to the sum of the worker contribution and the firm contribution. The computer generates a random suggested wage that correlates with the worker contribution. Workers in the Choice treatment can decide to enter into a negotiation with the firm or to forgo the negotiation by accepting the suggested wage. Workers in the Always treatment enter negotiations while still observing the suggested wage. All negotiations concern the share of joint revenue the worker receives as a wage. Negotiations that fail to reach an agreement result in the suggested wage being implemented along with a five-dollar impasse penalty for both the worker and the firm. Appendix B contains the instructions given to participants. These instructions include information on workers and firms as well as screenshots of how negotiations take place. Instructions are read out loud to guarantee that the structure of the experiment is common information. Before turning to the description and motivation for each design element, we note that our design purposefully limits three channels that have been shown to generate gender differences in negotiations.7 First, individuals know their individual contributions to prevent gender differences in confidence about what one brings to the table (Niederle and Vesterlund, 2007; Mobius et al., 2014). Second, negotiations are anonymous to reduce potential fears of backlash among women in particular (Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Tinsley et al., 2009; Amanatullah and Morris, 2010; Amanatullah and Tinsley, 2013). Third, the negotiation opportunity is explicit to reduce the potential for gender differences arising from uncertainty about whether a negotiation is possible (Small et al., 2007; Leibbrandt and List, 2015). Individual Contributions and Joint Revenue Participants perform a five-minute real-effort task at the beginning of each of the two negotiation blocks. Their performance determines their individual contribution for the subsequent five rounds of negotiation opportunities in that block. A worker’s contribution is $20, $15 or $10, depending on whether the worker’s performance is the highest, second highest or third highest when compared to two other randomly selected workers. A firm’s contribution is $25 or $20, 7 To examine whether increased negotiations are beneficial to women, we sought to design an environment where negotiations are generally profitable for women. Showing that increased negotiations are not helpful to women in an environment where women rarely do well in negotiations would be less informative. 4 depending on whether the firm’s performance is the highest or second highest performance when compared to one other randomly selected firm. Any performance ties are broken randomly, and all participants are informed that this process determines contributions. In the first block, the real-effort task is to calculate the sum of five two-digit numbers. In the second block, the task is to count the number of zeros in a table with ten rows and five columns of zeros and ones (i.e., one row may appear like “00101”). Since participants’ relative performances may vary across the two tasks, their individual contributions may vary across the two blocks. After learning their individual contributions for a block, participants face five rounds of negotiation opportunities. In each round, a firm and a worker are randomly paired, and the joint revenue is the sum of the worker and firm contributions. By making contribution levels not depend linearly on performances and instead imply a set of contribution levels, we ensure that variation in individual contribution levels can be easily explained. The variance in individual contribution levels also generates multiple focal points of the negotiation. In addition to arguing for “equal splits” where the joint revenue is split 50-50, individuals may argue for “equity splits” where the joint revenue is split proportionally according to their individual contributions. The potential insistence on equity splits may result from individuals feeling entitled to their contribution and seeing it as the relevant reference point, particularly since individual performances determine individual contribution levels (Konow, 2000).8 On the other hand, the highest contribution level of the worker equals the lowest contribution level of the firm, which may help workers justify requests that exceed their individual contribution levels.9 The firm is always informed of the worker contribution. Whether the worker is informed of the firm contribution depends on the study version. In a common information version, the worker is informed of the firm contribution. In a private information version, the worker is not informed of the firm contribution. This variation in information is motivated by the finding that women often fare worse in negotiations that involve more ambiguity (see Bowles and McGinn (2008) and Mazei et al. (2015) for reviews, or Leibbrandt and List (2015) for recent evidence). However, perhaps given the anonymity and explicit choice to negotiate in our setting, this variation in knowledge does not produce significantly different results.10 Our analysis will therefore not focus on this variation and instead includes it as a control where relevant. 8 Feeling entitled may influence individuals’ decisions as shown in Hoffman et al. (1994) and discussed more broadly in Engel (2011). Since much of this work examines dictator games, it is interesting to note that Demiral and Mollerstrom (2018) do not find evidence for an entitlement effect in ultimatum games. 9 See Konow, Saijo and Akai (2016) for a discussion on “equality” and “equity” principles of fairness. The equity principle may also be referred to as being Libertarian (Almås et al., 2010). For earlier work showing that multiple reference points and fairness principles can result in diverse negotiation outcomes see also Roth and Murnighan (1982). 10 For instance, workers enter negotiations 72% of the time when there is private information and 69% of the time when there is common information. We fail to reject the equality of the entrance rates (p = 0.36) and the equality of the average profit from negotiations of $1.31 vs $1.23 conditional on negotiations (p = 0.74). 5 Suggested Wage and Potential Payoffs In the Choice treatment, a worker can choose to avoid negotiations by accepting a “suggested wage.” The suggested wage for a worker equals the worker contribution plus a bonus that in each round is randomly and uniformly drawn from the set -4, -2, 0, 2. While workers know that the suggested wage is random, they do not know the details of the process. However, knowing their own contribution levels, workers can determine the extent to which suggested wages differ from their own contributions. If a worker accepts a suggested wage, the firm receives the joint revenue minus the suggested wage. If a worker instead enters a negotiation in the Choice treatment, or when a worker always negotiates in the Always treatment, two payoff scenarios are possible. When an agreement is reached, the worker receives the agreed upon wage and the firm receives the remainder of the joint revenue. When an agreement is not reached, the suggested wage is implemented along with a five-dollar impasse penalty for both the worker and firm. That is, the worker receives the suggested wage minus five dollars, and the firm receives the joint revenue minus the suggested wage minus five dollars. Table 1 summarizes these potential payoffs. One round from each block is randomly selected for payment. Table 1: Worker Payoffs (W) and Firm Payoffs (F) No Negotiation Negotiation Agreement Negotiation Impasse Choice treatment Always Treatment W = suggested wage N/A F = joint revenue - suggested wage W = agreed upon wage F = joint revenue - agreed upon wage W = suggested wage - $5 F = joint revenue - suggested wage - $5 W indicates the payoff for the worker, and F indicates the payoff for the firm. In the Choice treatment, a worker may decide to accept the suggested wage and thus not enter a negotiation. The resulting payoffs are shown in the No Negotiation row. Alternatively, a worker may choose to reject the suggested wage and enter a negotiation. Payoffs when an agreement is reached are shown in the Negotiation Agreement row, while payoffs when an agreement in not reached are shown in the Negotiation Impasse row. In the Always treatment, workers always enter negotiations so only these latter two payoffs are relevant. The suggested wage serves as a focal point for negotiations, as agreed upon wages should fall within $5 of the suggested wage. Outside of the resulting $10 range for a given suggested wage, a payoff dominant strategy – for either the worker or the firm – would instead involve a negotiation impasse which implements the suggested wage with the $5 penalty. Assuming risk neutrality, the suggested wage indeed corresponds to the symmetric Nash Bargaining Solution since it results – with a symmetric $5 penalty – from an impasse. There are thus three potential focal points for negotiations: the equal split, the equity split, and the symmetric Nash Bargaining Solution (i.e., implementing the suggested wage). 6 In varying the extent to which a suggested wage differs from an individual’s contribution, the random bonus helps us assess how outcomes from negotiations and entry into negotiations vary with an observable characteristic of the negotiations. While the Nash Bargaining solution predicts that the outcomes from negotiations are independent of bonus, both the equality and equity principles of fairness suggest that how much a worker benefits from a negotiation decreases as the bonus increases. We therefore expect a negative bonus (of -4 or -2) to represent an easier and potentially more favorable negotiation opportunity. For instance, when the suggested wage is less than the worker’s contribution, a worker may find it easier to appeal to the equity fairness principle to justify why they should receive a wage that is greater than their suggested wage. A non-negative bonus (of 0 or 2) may instead represent a more difficult and less favorable negotiation opportunity, as workers may find it more difficult to negotiate a wage that improves upon the suggested wage since doing so involves arguing for more than their contribution. Assigning a $5 impasse penalty achieves three purposes in our study. First, it opens up room for losses in negotiation to occur even if an agreement is reached. That is, workers may agree to a negotiated wage that is $1-$5 below their suggested wage to avoid impasse and the resulting loss of $5. Losses from negotiations, even in the event of an agreement, may arise in contexts outside of our study due to factors such as future costs in the form of backlash (Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Tinsley et al., 2009; Amanatullah and Morris, 2010; Amanatullah and Tinsley, 2013), damage to one’s reputation, costs in regard to decreased profits from future negotiations, loss of goodwill or loss from the worker subsequently being seen as a weak negotiator. Second, assigning an impasse penalty allows us to make explicit the financial costs from disagreement, as is common in bargaining experiments.11 Of course, there may also be psychological costs in the form of embarrassment or disutility from being seen as failing. Costs of impasse are often an important feature to negotiations in contexts outside of our study as well. For instance, an impasse today can result in even larger losses in future collaborations, escalating backlash, financial costs of decreased reputation, or decreased likelihood of cooperation after what may be seen as a defection (e.g., Dal Bó and Fréchette, 2018, and Dreber et al., 2008). Third and finally, the answer to our question on whether women and men would benefit from negotiating more is obvious absent a potential downside to negotiation. If there is no risk or potential cost to negotiating (e.g., if the suggested wage is always guaranteed), profits would be maximized by negotiating all the time. Also, in using a fixed cost of $5, we hold the impasse cost independent of the individual’s worker-firm role and of the individual’s contributions, thus ensuring that the range of individually rational agreements in every negotiation is $10. 11 Common costs of bargaining impasse in negotiation studies include the total destruction of surplus in the ultimatum game (Güth, Schmittberger and Schwarze, 1982) and in unstructured negotiations experiments such as Roth and Murnighan (1982). For an early overview of negotiation experiments see e.g., Roth (1995). Similar to our design, Babcock and Loewenstein (1997) use a fixed cost of bargaining impasse in the form of “legal fees,” which are strictly smaller than the total amount to be divided. 7 Negotiations The structure of negotiations is public knowledge and is as follows. Workers and firms have three minutes to send each other instant chat messages. Messages are not allowed to identify participants in any way, such as containing their name, age or gender. While chat messages can be used to discuss different wages, no agreements can be implemented through the chat itself. Instead, official wage proposals must be entered into a separate table. Individuals can update proposals at any time by submitting a new one to the table. All wage proposals must be in dollars (i.e., integer values). An agreement is reached only if a participant explicitly accepts an opponent’s most recent wage proposal by clicking the “I accept this offer” button. In the Always treatment, negotiations always occur. By contrast, in the Choice treatment, negotiations only occur when the worker chooses to enter a negotiation.12 When a negotiation occurs and an agreement is reached prior to the completion of 3 minutes, the worker and firm can no longer communicate but must wait for the remainder of the 3 minutes. When no negotiation occurs due to a worker choosing not to negotiate, the worker and firm can never communicate and instead wait for the 3 minutes to pass. The chat messages help to make the negotiations more realistic. Requiring formal wage proposals, meanwhile, ensures that the negotiations are tractable. The well-defined parameters of the negotiation environment, including the strict time limit, decrease structural ambiguity. Follow-up activities After participants complete both blocks of five negotiation rounds, we elicit risk and fairness measures over payoffs similar to those faced when workers decide whether to negotiate. To measure how participants respond to risk, they make a series of five binary choices between (1) $13 for certain and (2) a lottery of $18 with P % chance and $8 with (1 − P )% chance. From the first to fifth choice, P increases in increments of 10 percentage points from 50% to 90%. Participants learn that one of these choices from one decision maker in each session will be implemented for payment.13 This measure of risk allows us to examine whether gender differences in entry into negotiations are due to potential gender differences in risk aversion. The gambles are structured so that they mirror the potential risk a participant faces when choosing between accepting a suggested wage of $13 or entering a negotiation. That is, when entering such a negotiation, a participant would receive $8 as a result of the $5 penalty if an agreement is not reached or $18 by instead fully 12 When a worker is deciding whether to negotiate, their firm is told “If the worker you were matched with chooses to negotiate in this round, you will be given 3 minutes to negotiate and will begin this negotiation in a few seconds. Otherwise, you will be directed to a waiting screen where you will need to wait for 3 minutes while the negotiation round completes.” 13 In our initial experiment at Stanford University, a mistake in the payment code resulted in participants receiving too large of a payment: one of these choices for each participant was implemented for payment. In our replication experiment at the University of Pittsburgh, this was fixed: one of these choices from one decision marker in each session was implemented for payment. 8 capturing $5 from the individually rational bargaining range of +/- $5 around the suggested wage.14 To elicit perceptions of fairness, participants are asked to select a wage in six scenarios that vary according to the worker contribution, the firm contribution and the suggested wage.15 In each session, we randomly select one decision maker and implement one scenario for payment for an unrelated worker-firm pair. To encourage participants’ allocations to reflect their own views on fairness and their expectations of others’ views on fairness, the worker-firm pair award the decision-maker a bonus, from $0 to $10, according to how fair they view the decision maker’s implemented wage. This measure of fairness allows us to examine if workers’ entry decisions are driven by fairness perceptions. For instance, we can ask whether workers whose fairness perceptions are inclined towards the equity principle of fairness – i.e., that a wage should reflect what workers bring to the table – are less likely to enter negotiations in which their suggested wage equals or exceeds their individual contribution. Finally, participants complete a short follow-up survey that collects demographic information on their age, sex, graduation year, degree program, and GPA. 3 Data From May - October 2013, 292 undergraduate students participated in sixteen sessions at the Stanford Economics Research Laboratory (SERL). We used the online recruiting system Sona, following standard SERL procedures. The study was advertised as a 120-minute “Standard Lab Study” with an average payment of $40 and without any further details about the study. The modal session achieved gender-balance with the percentage of female participants ranging from 42% to 63% across sessions.16 Nearly all participants (96%) were between 18 and 22 years old. Most participants expected to graduate from the School of Humanities & Sciences (56%), followed by the School of Engineering (24%) and those who had not decided on a major (15%). From the two randomly selected negotiation rounds (one from each block), additional payments from the follow-up activities and a $5 show-up fee, cash earnings ranged from $22 - $99 with an average of $56. In the Always treatment, there were 33 female workers, 31 male workers, 34 female firms and 30 male firms. In the Choice treatment, there were 41 female workers, 41 14 We chose $13 as it reflects a “middle” suggested wage that arises from a worker contribution of $15 and a bonus of -2. Also, while workers can reach agreements outside the range of their suggested wage plus or minus $5, doing so requires the worker or firm to forgo a strictly dominant (financial) outcome of failing to reach an agreement and hence having the suggested wage with the $5 penalty implemented as the worker’s wage. Indeed, only 2.6% of negotiations result in workers receiving a wage outside of this range. 15 The scenarios (worker contribution, firm contribution, suggested wage) are: (10, 25, 10), (15, 25, 15), (20, 25, 20), (20, 25, 14), (20, 25, 16), and (20, 25, 22). 16 Aiming for gender-balance, we used Sona to recruit two sets of participants for each session – male and female participants. Participants cannot view studies that they are not eligible for on Sona, which allows us to recruit separately by gender and thus discretely secure that equal numbers of men and women are signed up for a session. 9 male workers, 38 female firms, and 44 male firms. For each participant, we observe 10 rounds of negotiation data. These data allow us to determine if and when male and female workers choose to enter negotiations and their profits from doing so. We compute profits as the worker’s payoff minus their suggested wage. When workers choose not to enter negotiations in the Choice treatment, their profits are thus zero. Conditional on negotiations, their profits depend on whether an agreement is reached. In the case of agreement, the profit is negative, zero, or positive whenever the agreed upon wage falls below, equals, or exceeds the suggested wage. In the case of impasse, the profit is negative five dollars by design. To examine how participants engage in free-form chat when they enter negotiations, we hired three undergraduate research assistants at an hourly rate to indicate for each round of negotiations whether the firm and/or worker sent chat messages that could be classified as using aggression, compromise, deference, entitlement, even-split arguments, fairness concepts, needbased appeals, and/or norms.17 We consider an individual’s chat message to fall into one of the above categories for a given round if two or more research assistants indicated the relevance of that category. We also hired one research assistant to indicate the chance (from 0 to 100%) that a particular round of anonymized chat messages was sent by a female. In addition to being paid an hourly rate, this research assistant was paid a bonus according to the accuracy of 10 randomly selected guesses.18 Before turning to our data on workers’ decisions to negotiate and the profits from doing so, we note that there are no gender differences in the other measures we collect for workers.19 First, there are neither significant gender differences in the individual contribution levels nor in the 17 An overview of the provided definitions for these chat categories are as follows: aggressive - a participant threatens to not reach an agreement or strongly questions their partner’s proposal; compromise - a participant explicitly suggests they take into account their own preference and their partner’s preference; deferential - a participant talks poorly of themselves or favorably of their partner, is apologetic, is uncertain, uses caveats, or looks for assurance (particularly via the use of question marks); entitled - a participant advocates for higher payment by saying they deserve it for some reason; even-split - a participant explicitly says they should split the joint revenue equally; fair - a participant uses the word fair or a close synonym for fair; need-based - a participant discusses their financial need for the money; norm - a participant discusses what they have received or how payments have been determined in past rounds. Among the non-self-selected negotiations in the Always treatment, the following chat tendencies occur less than 10% of the time and are excluded from the remaining analysis: compromise, even-split, norm and needy. There are no significant gender differences in any of the remaining chat tendencies: aggressive, deferential, entitled and fair. 18 Specifically, the research assistant knew that for each of the selected guesses, we would randomly draw an integer X from 1 to 100. If X was less than or equal to his percentage guess that the message was sent by a female, he would receive $10 if the message was indeed sent by a female and $0 otherwise. If X was greater than his percentage guess that the message was sent by a female, he would receive $10 with a X% chance and $0 otherwise. Among the negotiations in the Always treatment – the research assistant correctly guessed, on average, a higher chance that a message was sent by a female worker if that indeed was the case (51% versus 46%, two-sided t-test p < 0.01). 19 For firms there are likewise no significant gender differences in these other measures with one exception: our risk measure indicates that female firms are significantly more risk averse than male firms. This difference does not result in negotiation outcomes for firms differing by gender. 10 performances that help to determine the individual contributions. On the task that involves calculating the sum of five two-digit numbers, the average individual contribution level is $14.59 among female workers and $14.58 among male workers (two-sided t-test, p = 0.99).20 When the task involves counting the number of zeros in a table with 50 numbers, the average individual contribution level is $15.20 among female workers and $14.79 among male workers (two-sided t-test, p = 0.56).21 Second, there are no gender differences in our measure of risk aversion: the number of times (i) a certain amount of $13 is chosen over (ii) a lottery of $18 with P % chance and $8 with (1 − P )% chance. There are five such lotteries where P is 50%, 60%, 70%, 80%, or 90%. The certain option is chosen an average of 2.28 times by female workers and 2.06 times by male workers (two-sided t-test, p = 0.26). Given that only 3 workers have multiple switching points, this implies that the average worker chooses the lottery of $18 with P% chance once P is approximately 70%. Third, there are no significant differences in our measure of fairness concerns. Out of the six scenarios that involve different worker contributions, firm contributions, and suggested wages, the perceived fair wage is set to equal the worker’s individual contribution level 2.53 times by female workers and 2.99 times by male workers (two-sided t-test, p = 0.25). 4 Results We consider two key questions. First, we ask whether always negotiating is financially beneficial. Second, we ask whether there is evidence of non-random and systematic selection into negotiations. After answering these two questions separately for female workers in Section 4.1 and male workers in Section 4.2, we explore in Section 4.3 whether our results vary by gender and whether they justify a greater push to negotiate for women than for men. In Section 4.4, we expand upon our second question by examining whether workers select on observable characteristics of the negotiation and/or individual characteristics that are unobservable to us. To assess the benefits of negotiation, we focus on a worker’s improvement in earnings from negotiations. Recall that in the Choice treatment the decision to negotiate implies giving up the suggested wage, and the worker’s profit from negotiation is thus the difference between the worker’s payoffs from the negotiation and the suggested wage. We compute the worker’s profit from negotiation in the same manner in the Always treatment. This allows us to evaluate the consequences of always negotiating and thus forgoing the option of taking the suggested wage, though that option is of course only available in the Choice treatment.22 20 The average correct number of answers is 9.92 among female workers and 10.67 among males workers (twosided t-test, p = 0.22). 21 The average correct number of answers is 21.95 among female workers and 22.35 among male workers (twosided t-test, p = 0.66). 22 While earnings are another measure of the success of always negotiating, they are a more noisy one, as they directly depend on the worker contribution and the bonus. 11 4.1 Women’s Negotiation Decisions and Outcomes Results from our Choice treatment show that female workers enter negotiations 66% of the time. Out of the 41 female workers, only one never enters a negotiation and four enter all negotiations. Entering negotiations is largely beneficial: agreements are reached 89% of the time, a substantial 74% of negotiations result in gains while only 13% result in losses. The average profit achieved from entering negotiations is $1.45. Consistent with the evidence often used to support the recommendation for increased negotiations, women often avoid negotiations even though negotiations are largely beneficial. To answer our first question on whether women would financially benefit from negotiating more often, it is not sufficient to consider the profits that result when women chose to negotiate in the Choice treatment. Rather, we need to compare the profits achieved by women in the Choice treatment to the counterfactual of the profits achieved by women in the Always treatment. To answer our second question regarding selection into negotiations, only profits that result from negotiations are relevant.23 That is, the answer to our second question requires a comparison of the profits from “self-selected” negotiations (those where workers choose to enter negotiations in the Choice treatment) to the profits from “non-self-selected” negotiations (those in the Always treatment). While no differences between the self-selected negotiations and non-self-selected negotiations would indicate random selection, outcomes from self-selected negotiations exceeding (or falling short of) those from non-self-selected negotiations would indicate positive (or negative) selection into negotiations. Addressing whether women financially benefit from always negotiating, Figure 1 shows the profits female workers achieve — the difference between the final wage and the suggested wage — in the Choice and Always treatments. As a result of the many negotiations that are not entered in the Choice treatment, many secure zero profits in that treatment. The remainder of the distribution shows that negotiations are mostly successful and result in gains. The vast majority of negotiations yield a wage that exceeds the suggested wage. The distribution of profits in the Always treatment sheds light on what would happen if, instead of forgoing 34% of negotiations, women always negotiated. Not surprisingly, the share of zero profits decreases in the Always treatment, as it is not possible simply to accept the suggested wage. These additional negotiations, however, do not mirror the positive profits seen in the Choice treatment. Relative to the Choice treatment, there is no increase in the share of negotiations that raise earnings above the suggested wage in the Always treatment. Increased 23 While the analyses concerning these two questions are closely related, they are importantly distinct. For instance, when not conditioning on negotiations as in our first question, imagine that profits reflecting losses are more likely in the Always than in the Choice treatment. When conditioning on negotiations, the fraction of profits reflecting losses in the Choice treatment will increase due to the exclusion of zero-profits that result from a choice not to negotiate. Thus, it need not follow that profits reflecting losses are also more likely in the Always than the Choice treatment, when conditioning on negotiations. 12 negotiations are not helpful to women, as they do not avoid negotiations that would have resulted in gains. Not only do we observe that increased negotiations are not helpful to women, we further observe that increased negotiations result in more losses. The share of losses more than triples from 9% in the Choice treatment to 33% in the Always treatment (two-sided t-test, p < 0.01). This increase in losses does not result from increased impasse in the Always treatment. The rate of impasse insignificantly decreases from 11% in the Choice treatment to 8% in the Always treatment (two-sided t-test, p = 0.36). 0 20 Percent 40 60 80 Figure 1: Distribution of profits among female workers 0 Always Treatment Notes: This figure shows how often participants’ profits are less than 0, equal to 0, or greater than 0. Data include the observations from the 41 female workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment, and the 33 female workers during the 10 rounds in the Always treatment. The distribution of profits in Figure 1 draws from all bonus levels. In reproducing this distribution for each bonus level, Appendix Figure A.1 documents that at no bonus level do increased negotiations result in substantially more gains. While the lack of additional gains cannot easily be seen among the negotiation opportunities with negative bonuses of -4 and -2, since nearly all of those negotiations are entered (88%), it is clearly seen among the negotiation opportunities with the non-negative bonuses of 0 and 2, where only 44% of negotiations are entered. Table 2 confirms these findings via regression results. These regression results control for observable factors about the negotiations, including round fixed effects and individual contributions to the joint revenue. These regression results also account for small sample size considerations while allowing for within cluster correlation and across cluster heteroskedasticity. In particular, standard errors are clustered at the participant-level and computed via the wild cluster bootstrap method with replacement 1,000 times using the method in Cameron and Miller (2015).24 Since 24 To do so, we use the code developed by Judson Caskey (see https://sites.google.com/site/judsoncaskey/data). 13 this method involves resampling t-statistics, note that p-values instead of standard errors are shown in parentheses. In the odd columns, the coefficient estimates on the Always indicator capture the differences in outcomes in the Always treatment relative to those in the Choice treatment when pooling across all bonuses. In the even columns, the coefficient estimates on the Always indicator instead capture the differences in outcomes in the Always treatment relative to those in the Choice treatment among negotiation opportunities with non-negative bonuses (because of the inclusion of the Always*b < 0 indicator). This latter specification is of particular interest since the high entry rate into negotiations with negative bonuses mechanically leaves little room for changes in profits as a result of increased negotiations.25 Columns 1 - 4 of Table 2 confirm the results on the distribution of profits shown in Figure 1.26 Increased negotiations do not increase the frequency of gains (Columns 1 - 2) but do significantly increase the frequency of losses by 24 percentage points when pooling across bonuses (Column 3) and by 39 percentage points when considering the non-negative bonuses (Column 4). Thus, in examining the extensive margin results, we observe no evidence for women avoiding negotiation opportunities that would have resulted in gains yet substantial and significant evidence for women avoiding negotiation opportunities that would have resulted in losses. In jointly considering the extensive and intensive margins, the results in Columns 5 - 6 further show that increased negotiations do not result in higher average profits for women. Instead, increased negotiations result in insignificantly lower average profits when pooling across bonuses (Column 5) and significantly lower profits when focusing on non-negative bonuses (Column 6).27 Rather than finding that women benefit from increased negotiations, our results suggest that it hurts them.28 We provide four additional pieces of evidence of increased negotiations not financially benefiting women. First, not only does the likelihood of gains not increase in the Always treatment relative to the Choice treatment, the size of gains does not significantly increase (Columns 7 8). Second, not only does the likelihood of losses increase in the Always treatment relative to the Choice treatment, the size of the losses increases (Columns 9 - 10). Third, Appendix Table A.1 shows that our results are robust to the exclusion of controls. Fourth, the downward shift 25 As detailed in Section 2, and evident via our exogenous variation of bonus levels, we ex-ante expected bonus levels to influence negotiation outcomes. Section 4.4 explores the important role of the bonus in driving selection into negotiations. 26 We see the distributional results as more informative than average profits, because the latter is directly influenced by parameters of the experiment. That is, average profits, more so than changes in the distribution of profits, is sensitive to the parameters of the experiment, such as specific distributions of the bonus level and the $5 impasse penalty. 27 Not surprisingly given the high entry rate when the bonus is negative, there is not a significant impact on average profits from increased negotiations when the bonus is negative. However, it remains directionally negative and thus shows that increased negotiations are not financially beneficial even when the bonus is negative. 28 As seen in Section 5, the mean effect on profits is significant in our replication with a larger sample at the University of Pittsburgh. 14 Table 2: Profits among female workers 1(profit > 0) (1) Always (2) 0.00 0.05 (0.95) (0.58) b 0 (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.24∗∗∗ 0.39∗∗∗ -0.44 -0.79∗∗∗ 0.23 -0.14 (0.00) (0.00) (0.13) (0.00) (0.29) (0.58) 0.04 1.30∗∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗ (0.14) (0.00) (0.01) -0.29∗∗∗ 0.62∗ 0.47 (0.00) (0.09) (0.13) -0.03 0.02 1.18 -0.87 1.11 -0.12 (0.84) (0.92) (0.28) (0.44) (0.19) (0.90) yes no yes no yes no yes yes yes yes yes yes 740 740 740 740 361 361 profit, given profit ≤ 0 (9) (10) profit, given negotiation (11) (12) -0.95∗∗∗ -1.15∗∗∗ -0.64∗∗ -1.24∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) (0.04) (0.00) -1.30∗∗ 1.07∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.00) 0.59 0.83∗ (0.36) (0.07) -0.94 0.34 1.25 -0.58 (0.35) (0.70) (0.34) (0.68) yes no yes no yes yes yes yes 379 379 601 601 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01. Standard errors are clustered at the participant-level and computed via the wild cluster bootstrap method with replacement 1,000 times. Since this method involves resampling tstatistics, p-values instead of standard errors are shown in parentheses. Results are from ordinary least squares regressions of the indicated measure of profits from negotiations: worker earnings - suggested wage. Always is an indicator for the Always treatment. b < 0 is an indicator for a negative bonus. Bonus FEs include indicators for each bonus level except for b = −4. The included controls are the negotiation round (from 1 to 10), the worker contribution, the difference between the worker’s and firm’s contributions, an indicator for whether the firm contribution is known, and the interaction between these last two variables. Columns 1 - 6 include all outcomes from the 41 female workers during the 10 rounds of the Choice treatment and the 33 female workers during the 10 rounds of the Always treatment, while Columns 7 - 8 include all of those outcomes that result in positive profits and Columns 9 -10 include all of those outcomes that result in non-positive profits. Columns 11 - 12 restrict to only outcomes from negotiations. in the distribution of profits in our Choice treatment relative to our Always treatment allows us to precisely and non-parametrically reject (p < 0.001) the equality of these distributions using a two-sample Kolmogorov-Smirnov test. Thus, the answer to our first question is clear: there is no evidence that women financially benefit from increased negotiations. Increased negotiations instead result in women entering more negotiations that are financially harmful. Since women appear to know when to ask, these findings are also suggestive in terms of answering our second question on whether we observe non-random and systematic selection into negotiations. Relative to profits from self-selected negotiations in the Choice treatment, the average profits from the non-self-selected negotiations in the Always treatment are significantly lower when pooling across bonuses (Column 11) and when focusing on non-negative bonuses (Column 12). Thus, the answer to our second question is clear: women positively select into negotiations. 4.2 Men’s Negotiation Decisions and Outcomes Results from the Choice treatment show that male workers enter negotiations 74% of the time. All 41 male workers enter at least one negotiation, and 7 of them enter all negotiations. 15 Entering negotiations is beneficial: agreements are reached 84% of the time, a substantial 71% of negotiations result in gains and only 19% result in losses. The average profit achieved from entering negotiations is $1.12. As with female workers, this positive profit from negotiating need not imply an affirmative answer to our first question on whether increased negotiations are financially beneficial for men. Figure 2 compares the profits achieved by men in the Choice treatment to the profits achieved by men in the Always treatment. Consistent with men opting out of negotiations 26% of the time in the Choice treatment, the frequency of zero profits is smaller in the Always treatment. The additional negotiations, however, do not result in more gains in the Always treatment than in the Choice treatment (54% versus 53%, two-sided t-test, p = 0.82). The additional negotiations instead increase losses from 14% in the Choice treatment to 25% in the Always treatment (twosided t-test, p < 0.01). The increase in losses is not driven by an increase in the rate of impasse. The rate of impasse is significantly smaller in the Always treatment than in the Choice treatment (8% versus 16%, two-sided t-test, p < 0.01). 0 20 Percent 40 60 80 Figure 2: Distribution of profits among male workers 0 Always Treatment Notes: This figure shows how often participants’ profits are less than 0, equal to 0, or greater than 0. Data include the 41 male workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment, and the 31 male workers during the 10 rounds in the Always treatment. In reproducing the distribution of profits for each bonus level, Appendix Figure A.2 documents a similar pattern. Increased negotiations do not result in substantially more gains at any bonus level. While the lack of additional gains cannot be seen among the negotiation opportunities with negative bonuses of -4 and -2, since nearly all of those negotiations are entered (97%), it is clearly seen among the negotiation opportunities with the non-negative bonuses of 0 and 2, where only 55% of negotiations are entered. Despite men avoiding approximately half of the negotiations with non-negative bonuses, we observe no evidence for men avoiding negotiations that would have been financially beneficial. 16 Table 3 (which reproduce the specifications from Table 2 for male workers) confirms the results on the distribution of profits.29 Increased negotiations do not increase the frequency of gains (Columns 1 - 2) but do significantly increase the frequency of losses by 11 percentage points when pooling across bonuses (Column 3) and by 27 percentage points when considering the non-negative bonuses (Column 4). Increased negotiations also do not result in higher average profits for men. Instead, increased negotiations have a near-zero impact on average profits when pooling across bonuses (Column 5) and significantly lower profits when focusing on non-negative bonuses (Column 6). Table 3: Profits among male workers 1(profit > 0) (1) (2) Ordinary least squares of 1(profit < 0) profit profit, given profit > 0 (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) -0.01 -0.03 0.11∗∗∗ 0.27∗∗∗ -0.03 (0.92) (0.60) (0.00) (0.00) (0.86) b 0) (1) Always (2) 0.00 0.01 (0.96) (0.91) b 0 (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.24∗∗∗ 0.40∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) 0.04∗ (0.08) -0.30∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.05∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ (0.03) (0.01) -0.13∗∗ -0.14∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.01) -0.03 0.01 (0.76) (0.92) yes no yes yes 1460 1460 -0.45∗ -0.89∗∗∗ (0.10) (0.00) 1.36∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.80∗∗∗ (0.00) -0.07 -0.07 (0.71) (0.70) 0.42 0.44 (0.25) (0.23) 1.46∗ -0.57 (0.06) (0.47) yes no yes yes 1460 1460 0.23 -0.10 (0.26) (0.67) 0.73∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.44∗ (0.05) 0.10 0.12 (0.62) (0.52) -0.19 -0.23 (0.50) (0.38) 1.82∗∗∗ 0.57 (0.00) (0.33) yes no yes yes 743 743 profit, given profit ≤ 0 (9) (10) profit, given negotiation (11) (12) -0.92∗∗∗ -1.26∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) -1.78∗∗∗ (0.00) 1.08∗∗ (0.03) -0.67∗∗∗ -0.74∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.00) 0.85∗∗∗ 0.95∗∗∗ (0.01) (0.00) -0.91 0.70 (0.24) (0.30) yes no yes yes 717 717 -0.61∗∗ -1.25∗∗∗ (0.05) (0.00) 1.24∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.92∗∗ (0.01) -0.26 -0.27 (0.37) (0.35) 0.63 0.64 (0.13) (0.11) 1.61∗ -0.24 (0.08) (0.80) yes no yes yes 1216 1216 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01. Standard errors are clustered at the participant-level and computed via the wild cluster bootstrap method with replacement 1,000 times. Since this method involves resampling tstatistics, p-values instead of standard errors are shown in parentheses. Results are from ordinary least squares regressions of the indicated measure of profits from negotiations: worker earnings - suggested wage. Always is an indicator for the Always treatment. b < 0 is an indicator for a negative bonus. Male is an indicator for male workers. Bonus FEs include indicators for each bonus level except for b = −4. The included controls are the negotiation round (from 1 to 10), the worker contribution, the difference between the worker’s and firm’s contributions, an indicator for whether the firm contribution is known, and the interaction between these last two variables. Columns 1 - 6 include all outcomes from the 41 female workers and 41 male workers during the 10 rounds of the Choice treatment and the 33 female workers and 31 male workers during the 10 rounds of the Always treatment, while Columns 7 - 8 include all of those outcomes that result in positive profits and Columns 9 -10 include all of those outcomes that result in non-positive profits. Columns 11 - 12 restrict to only outcomes from negotiations. increased negotiations are, if anything, more harmful to women than they are to men. Increased negotiations result in significantly more losses for women than they do for men (Columns 3 -4) and, within the set of no gains, result in a significantly greater decrease in the average profit among women than they do among men (Columns 9 - 10). No other significant differences emerge (Columns 5 - 8, 11 - 12), and these results are robust to the exclusion of controls (see Appendix Table A.5). Thus, our results do not support the notion that men are more adept at knowing when to ask than women are. If anything, our results suggest that women are more adept at knowing when to ask.32 While this is notable given that female-targeted lean-in advice would suggest the 32 We do not observe similar gender differences when considering firms. Appendix Table A.8 (and Appendix A.4 more generally) demonstrates the lack of significant gender differences among the firms. The lack of a substantial gender difference among firms is consistent with prior literature — see for instance Andersen et al. (2013) and Dittrich, Knabe and Leipold (2014) — as the greater (appearing) bargaining power for firms may limit the potential of a gender difference. Although sex-pairings often influence negotiations (Eckel and Grossman, 19 opposite, it is not surprising in light of our earlier gender-specific analyses showing that increased negotiations are neither helpful to women nor to men. 4.4 Investigating the selection into negotiations on observable and unobservable characteristics Since we do not observe evidence for better selection into negotiations by men than women, this section examines two additional questions to examine whether there is evidence for better selection into negotiations by men than women when considering particular channels through which selection may operate. First, we ask whether men more than women select on observable advantageous characteristics of the negotiation environment. Second, we ask whether men more than women select into negotiations according to their individual advantageous characteristics that are unobservable us. With respect to observable characteristics of the negotiation environment, note that we vary one such central characteristic: the bonus. Our earlier results show that this characteristic is an important determinant of selection into negotiation. Recall that women are 44 percentage points more likely to enter negotiations with negative than non-negative bonuses (88% vs 44%, two-sided t-test, p < 0.01), and that men are similarly 42 percentage points more likely to enter negotiations with negative than non-negative bonuses (97% vs 55%, two-sided t-test, p < 0.01). Figure 3 shows negotiation entry by bonus level and reveals that the response to changes in bonus is similar for women and men. This results is confirmed by Column 1 of Table 5 (see the significantly negative coefficient on b as well as the small and insignificant coefficient on Male*b). Column 1 also shows that female workers are marginally less likely than male workers to enter into a negotiation (see the coefficient on Male, p = 0.06). While these findings show that workers select into negotiations based on the bonus, the results in Column 4 of Table 5 indicate that workers positively select into negotiations based on the bonus: increases in the bonus are significantly correlated with lower average profits in the Always treatment. Workers, by avoiding more negotiations as the bonus increases, avoid the least advantageous negotiation opportunities. We note that this pattern is in line with our expectation detailed in Section 2. When facing a negative bonus, the suggested wage is below the worker contribution, potentially making the firm more amenable to increasing the wage because of equity concerns. Meanwhile, increases in the bonus correspond to increases in the worker’s suggested wage, potentially making it more difficult to negotiate for a higher wage. Put differently, the combination of these results — that negotiation entry and profits are decreasing in the bonus — indicate that workers know how the bonus should influence their willingness to negotiate. They are more likely to enter “easier” negotiation opportunities (those with negative bonuses) than “more difficult” negotiation opportunities (those with non-negative bonuses). Finding that there 2001; Solnick, 2001; Bowles, Babcock and Lai, 2007; Hernandez-Arenaz and Iriberri, 2018b), we do not find corresponding evidence in our data, which may result from our use of anonymous negotiations. 20 0 Percent of Negotiations Entered 25 50 75 100 Figure 3: Entry decisions into negotiations -4 -2 0 2 Bonus Male Workers Female Workers Notes: This figure shows how often participants choose to enter negotiations given a bonus level. Data include the observations from the 41 female workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment and the 41 male workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment. are no significant gender differences, moreover, shows that men, no more than women, positively select into negotiations based off of the bonus. To examine whether workers select on their individual characteristics that are unobservable to us, we first ask whether entry decisions vary by bargaining ability. A key challenge to answering this question is that we need a measure of bargaining ability. While a natural measure is the profit to negotiation, it is essential that we measure ability where selection into negotiation does not play a substantial role. As such, we construct two ability measures from negotiations that nearly all workers enter: those involving a bonus of -4. Ability measure 1 is the average profit from all negotiations with a bonus of -4. Ability measure 2 is the average profit from all negotiations with a bonus of -4 that reach an agreement.33 Ability measure 2 is useful since a failure to reach an agreement results in a large loss, which could make the first ability measure quite noisy. Given that these ability measures are constructed from profits at a bonus of -4, we examine whether they are predictive of entry into more “difficult” negotiations (i.e., non-negative bonus negotiations) where there is substantial variation in entry. Columns 2 and 3 of Table 5 show the extent to which these ability measures are predictive of entry decisions when the bonus is non-negative. While female workers with higher ability 33 In principle, we could have considered many measures of ability, making multiple hypotheses testing a concern. While our restriction to ability measures where selection concerns are limited (i.e., at a bonus of -4) prevented the consideration of many potential measures of ability, we nonetheless note that these results – per other reasons mentioned in the text – are speculative in nature. 21 measures are significantly more likely to enter negotiations with non-negative bonuses (see the coefficient estimates on the ability measures), male workers with higher ability measures are not (the sums of the coefficient estimates on the ability measures and the interactions of the male indicator with the ability measures are not significantly different from zero). Columns 5 and 6 of Table 5 further show that these ability measures are correlated with higher average profits when the bonus is non-negative.34 These results therefore suggest that men are not more likely, and if anything appear less likely than women, to positively select on ability. Of course, that female but not male workers appear to positively select into negotiations on their ability is only suggestive as we may not be capturing the individual’s true unobserved ability.35 In closing, we provide evidence against other mechanisms that could contribute to our results. First, measures of participants’ fairness perceptions, risk aversion, or chat tendencies are not robustly predictive of entry decisions in the Choice treatment nor of the average profit in the Always treatment (see Appendix Table A.7).36 Our main results are also robust to controlling for these fairness perceptions and risk aversion measures (see Appendix Tables A.2, A.4, and A.6).37 Second, if workers dislike entering negotiations because they are uncomfortable with how their individual contribution levels are determined or fear the five-dollar impasse penalty, the high entry rate into negotiations at non-negative bonuses shows that the dislike is not sufficient to dissuade them from all negotiations. Third, if the observed evidence for positively selecting into negotiations is solely reflective of workers performing worse in negotiations because they have to negotiate, then non-self-selected negotiations from the Always treatment would yield worse outcomes than the self-selected negotiations from the Choice treatment regardless of the bonus. This is not the case (for instance, see the coefficient estimate on Always*b < 0 in Column 12 of Table 4). 34 While the ability measures are not differentially predictive of profits for men than women, for men only the second ability measure is significantly predictive of profits. 35 For our ability measure to capture actual ability, we would at a minimum need to assume that a worker’s bargaining ability is independent of the negotiating partner and does not change over time. 36 There is marginally significant evidence for fairness concerns influencing the selection into negotiations by both women and men, although fairness concerns are only significantly correlated with the average profit in the Always treatment by women. For chat tendencies, we note that the types of chat messages that occur less than 10% of the time are not included in Appendix Table A.7. For a more extensive discussion of the effectiveness of negotiation communication strategies, see Bowles (2013). 37 We do not examine if our main results are robust to controlling for chat tendencies because many of the observations examined in our main results do not involve chats. 22 Table 5: Considering the selection into negotiation on the bonus and on ability measures Linear probability model of entry into negotiation in Choice treatment (1) (2) (3) -0.10∗∗∗ (0.00) b -0.51∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.06∗∗∗ (0.01) Ability measure 1 Ability measure 2 Male Male*b 0.11∗ (0.06) 0.01 (0.72) 0.28∗∗∗ (0.00) Ability measure 2 *Male b Controls N 0.20∗ (0.05) 0.08∗∗ (0.02) 0.31∗∗ (0.03) 0.35 (0.18) -0.02 (0.90) -0.06∗ (0.06) Ability measure 1 *Male Constant Ordinary least squares of profit in Forced treatment (4) (5) (6) 0.91∗∗∗ (0.00) any yes 820 0.90∗∗∗ (0.00) b>0 yes 410 0.23 (0.57) 0.24∗∗ (0.03) 0.02 (0.98) -0.08 (0.49) -0.06 (0.20) 0.72∗∗∗ (0.00) b>0 yes 401 -2.89∗∗ (0.04) any yes 640 -2.22∗ (0.08) b>0 yes 314 -0.00 (0.99) -2.25∗ (0.08) b>0 yes 314 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01. Standard errors are clustered at the participant-level and computed via the wild cluster bootstrap method with replacement 1,000 times. Since this method involves resampling t-statistics, p-values instead of standard errors are shown in parentheses. Ability measure 1 is a worker’s average profit from negotiations involving a bonus of -4. Ability measure 2 is a worker’s average profit from negotiations involving a bonus of -4 that that reach agreements. Male is an indicator for being male. If the bottom b row indicates b > 0 , then the data are restricted to include negotiation opportunities with non-negative bonuses. Columns 1 -3: results are from ordinary least squares regressions of an indicator for whether a worker chooses to enter a negotiation; the included controls are the negotiation round (from 1 to 10), the worker contribution, an indicator for whether the firm contribution is known, and the difference between the worker’s and firm’s contributions if the firm contribution is known; and data include the observations from the 41 female workers and 41 male workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment. Columns 4 - 6: results are from ordinary least squares regressions of a worker’s profit; the included controls are the negotiation round (from 1 to 10), the worker contribution, an indicator for whether the firm contribution is known, the difference between the worker’s and firm’s contribution, and the interaction between these last two variables; and data include the 33 female workers and 31 male workers during the 10 rounds of the Always treatment. 5 A Replication at the University of Pittsburgh In September 2018, we replicated our study at the University of Pittsburgh Experimental Economics Laboratory (PEEL). Following precisely the design and procedures of the experiment at Stanford, we conducted a total of 20 sessions.38 The location of the experiment was changed to secure a larger sample than that of our initial experiment; our sample of 398 Pittsburgh 38 The only difference was that, as noted footnote 13, the previous coding error (resulting in Stanford participants receiving weakly more money that they should have from the risk aversion elicitation procedure) was corrected. 23 participants is 36% larger than our sample at Stanford. The results at Pittsburgh replicate those at Stanford. The results for female workers can be summarized as follows. Women frequently avoid negotiations: they enter negotiations 70% of the time. Negotiations they choose to enter are largely beneficial: agreements are reached 92% of the time, 82% of negotiations result in gains while only 11% result in losses, and the average profit achieved from negotiating is $1.84. Yet, increased negotiations are not financially helpful: they do not result in additional gains (see Columns 1 - 2 of Table 6) but do result in additional losses (see Columns 3 - 4 of Table 6). Indeed, women positively select into negotiations (see Columns 11 - 12 of Table 6). Figure 4 shows how always negotiating changes the distribution of gains and losses for women. The response at Pittsburgh is strikingly similar to that seen at Stanford (see Figure 1), and this is further confirmed when comparing the regression results in Table 6 to those shown in Table 2. While the regression results are similar in terms of magnitude, note that, as one may expect given the increase in sample size, we now easily reject a null effect on average profit of increasing negotiation. Specifically, when assessing whether increased negotiations fail to increase average profits in our Stanford experiment, Table 2 presents directional but not significant evidence of average profits decreasing (p = 0.13) when pooling across all bonuses (Column 5) and significant evidence when only considering the non-negative bonuses (Column 6). Table 6 shows that at Pittsburgh increased negotiations again fail to increase, and this time, significantly decrease average profits in both cases (Column 5 - 6). Indeed, forcing women to negotiate hurts them. More generally, Appendix A.5 shows that our results further replicate in that (i) increased negotiations are not financially helpful to men, (ii) increased negotiations are not more helpful — or more accurately, less harmful — to men than they are to women, (iii) men do not positively select into negotiations to a greater degree than women do, and (iv) both women and men appear to positively select into negotiations off of the observable characteristic of the negotiation environment (i.e., the bonuses). Only two noteworthy, but slight, differences emerge relative to the initial study. First, while it is still the case that female workers do not enter negotiations more often than male workers, we do not find that men and women enter negotiations at different rates. Second, we do not find evidence of a gender gap in selection on ability. Men and women both appear to positively select on our measure of ability. 24 0 20 Percent 40 60 80 Figure 4: With Pittsburgh data, distribution of profits among female workers 0 Always Treatment Notes: This figure shows how often participants’ profits are less than 0, equal to 0, or greater than 0. Data include the observations from the 54 female workers during the 10 rounds in the Choice treatment, and the 51 female workers during the 10 rounds in the Always treatment. Table 6: With Pittsburgh data, profits among female workers 1(profit > 0) (1) (2) -0.07∗ 0.01 (0.10) (0.90) b 0 (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.20∗∗∗ 0.30∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) -0.02 (0.47) -0.20∗∗∗ (0.00) -0.07 0.03 (0.58) (0.76) yes no yes yes 1050 1050 -0.52∗∗∗ -0.54∗∗ 0.15 0.30 (0.01) (0.02) (0.41) (0.22) 1.89∗∗∗ 1.09∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) 0.17 -0.11 (0.64) (0.68) 2.08∗∗ -0.34 2.70∗∗∗ 1.45∗∗ (0.02) (0.63) (0.00) (0.04) yes no yes no yes yes yes yes 1050 1050 573 573 ∗ profit, given profit ≤ 0 (9) (10) profit, given negotiation (11) (12) -0.63∗∗∗ -0.94∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.00) -1.25∗∗∗ (0.00) 1.12∗∗ (0.02) -1.22 -0.21 (0.15) (0.79) yes no yes yes 477 477 -0.68∗∗∗ -0.91∗∗∗ (0.00) (0.01) 1.68∗∗∗ (0.00) 0.38 (0.33) 2.20∗∗ -0.01 (0.03) (0.95) yes no yes yes 890 890 p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01. Standard errors are clustered at the participant-level and computed via the wild cluster bootstrap method with replacement 1,000 times. Since this method involves resampling tstatistics, p-values instead of standard errors are shown in parentheses. Results are from ordinary least squares regressions of the indicated measure of profits from negotiations: worker earnings - suggested wage. Always is an indicator for the Always treatment. b < 0 is an indicator for a negative bonus. Bonus FEs include indicators for each bonus level except for b = −4. The included controls are the negotiation round (from 1 to 10), the worker contribution, the difference between the worker’s and firm’s contributions, an indicator for whether the firm contribution is known, and the interaction between these last two variables. Columns 1 - 6 include all outcomes from the 54 female workers during the 10 rounds of the Choice treatment and the 51 female workers during the 10 rounds of the Always treatment, while Columns 7 - 8 include all of those outcomes that result in positive profits and Columns 9 -10 include all of those outcomes that result in non-positive profits. Columns 11 - 12 restrict to only outcomes from negotiations. 25 6 An Online Experiment on the Paternalistic Demand for Workers to Lean-in The widespread sentiment that “women should negotiate more” originates from the finding that women benefit from negotiating yet many women are reluctant to do so. Mirroring these two characteristics, the setting in our original Stanford experiment and the subsequent Pittsburgh experiment allows us to assess the counterfactual of increased negotiation. We find in both studies that increased negotiations do not benefit women. Our results demonstrate the central role of selection and serve as a caution against the recommendation that women should negotiate more. Our results also shed light on the consequence of providing different negotiation advice to women and men. Since increased negotiations are neither more helpful nor less harmful for women than they are for men, we observe no evidence that justifies more frequently encouraging women, rather than men, to negotiate. In considering the costs from increased negotiations, we note that they may be disproportionately imposed on women than men if the push for increased negotiations is greater for women than for men. To directly assess whether the push to negotiate varies by the gender of the potential negotiator and to determine the consequences of such differences, we conducted two additional experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk. We conducted a modified version of our Choice and Always treatments, where workers can or cannot opt out of a negotiation with a firm. We refer to these as being in our “first-party” experiment. We also conducted a “third-party” experiment, where a third party can influence a worker’s ability to opt out of a negotiation. We first describe the design and results of our third-party experiment and then briefly highlight the design and results from our first-party experiment (further details on the experiments are in Appendix A.6 and Appendix B). For our third-party experiment, we recruited 400 participants to complete a 10-minute study for a guaranteed payment of $1.50 during January 2018. Out of the 400 participants, 399 participants completed the study. Participants were informed that they would be asked three questions and that their answer to one of the questions would be randomly selected to count for additional payment. Participants were randomly assigned to either a female or a male version of the experiment, where all three questions were about other female workers (n=214) or about other male workers (n=185), thus making them “third-party” participants. The first question of the third-party experiment aimed to elicit lean-in norms and asked “Do you think women/men should negotiate their salary more often?” The third-party participants could answer “yes” or “no,” and were informed that, if the question was selected for payment, they would receive 50 cents as an additional bonus payment if they provided the same answer as the answer given by most other participants. This payment procedure, following that in 26 Krupka and Weber (2013), allows us to elicit an incentivized measure of norms surrounding the propensity by which men and women should negotiate more. Summarizing the responses to the first question, Column 1 of Table 7 reports results from a linear probability model of the likelihood that the third-party participants responded that women/men should negotiate their salaries more often. The coefficient estimate on the constant shows that 94% of the third-party participants who are asked about women respond affirmatively. The coefficient estimate on Asked about men shows a significant drop of 24 percentage points when the third-party participants are instead asked about men. That is, our results are consistent with a societal norm that favors increased negotiations for women more than for men. The second question of the third-party experiment asks the third-party participants whether they are willing to pay to eliminate an individual’s ability to opt out of a negotiation. In particular, each third-party participant is told, depending on the treatment, that they are matched with one male or female worker who will face a negotiation opportunity in a future study. While the third-party participant’s payment is not influenced by the outcome from this future negotiation, the outcome of the negotiation may be affected by the third-party participant eliminating the matched worker’s ability to opt out of a negotiation. In the event that the second question counts for payment, the third-party participant must decide whether to (i) receive 50 cents in additional payment, or instead (ii) pay 25 cents out of these 50 cents in additional payment to guarantee that the matched worker cannot opt out of a negotiation. Prior to answering this second question, the third-party participants are provided with information on the negotiation opportunities their matched workers will face. The characteristics of the negotiation are similar to that of our laboratory studies: The worker will be paired with one firm; the worker and the firm each contribute 150 cents to a joint revenue for a total of 300 cents; the worker is provided with a suggested wage: a suggestion of how many cents, out of the joint revenue, the worker should receive as a wage; the suggested wage is randomly selected to equal 120, 150, 180, or 210 cents; the worker must choose whether to negotiate with the firm; if the worker does not negotiate with the firm, the worker receives a wage equal to the suggested wage, and the firm receives the joint revenue minus the suggested wage; if the worker negotiates the worker proposes a wage and may provide a justification; if the firm accepts the wage proposal, it is implemented; if instead the firm rejects the wage proposal, the suggested wage is implemented with a 30 cent penalty applied to both the payoffs received by the worker and by the firm for failing to reach an agreement. The third-party participant is provided with no further information prior to deciding whether to prevent their matched worker from opting out of a negotiation. Notably, while the third-party participant knows that their matched worker will learn their suggested wage before deciding whether to enter a negotiation, the third-party participant does not know this suggested wage. The third-party participant only knows that suggested wages equal 120, 150, 180, or 210 cents. 27 The third-party participant also does not have any knowledge of the matched worker’s preferences or negotiation ability. Despite the limited information on the specific negotiation opportunities faced by their matched workers, we find that third-party participants pay to eliminate their matched workers’ ability to opt out of negotiations and that this willingness is greater when the matched worker is female. The coefficient estimate on the constant in Column 2 of Table 7 shows that the majority of third-party participants (55% of them) forgo half of their additional payment to eliminate a female worker’s ability to opt out of a negotiation. The coefficient on Asked about men shows that this willingness to restrict a worker’s choice is cut by half — significantly reduced by 23 percentage points — if third-party participants are instead matched with a male worker. These results provide evidence that a paternalistic demand for eliminating a worker’s ability to opt out of a negotiation is greater when the worker is female rather than male. Table 7: Results from third-party experiment: paternalistic lean-in Linear probability model of answering yes to women should negotiate willing to pay for women to negotiate more often more often (1) (2) (3) Asked about men -0.236∗∗∗ (0.037) -0.228∗∗∗ (0.048) 0.940∗∗∗ (0.017) 399 0.545∗∗∗ (0.035) 399 Entry belief Constant Observations -0.245∗∗∗ (0.049) 0.002∗∗ (0.001) 0.435∗∗∗ (0.066) 399 ∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01. Standard errors are robust and shown in parentheses. In Column 1, results are from ordinary least squares regressions of an indicator for whether a participant indicates that women/men should negotiate their salaries more often. In Column 2, results are from ordinary least squares regressions of an indicator for whether a participant is willing to pay for a woman/man to be forced to enter a negotiation. Data include the observations from the 399 workers in our third-party experiment. What gives rise to the greater push for women to negotiate more? Does it result from a perception that women negotiate less than men? To assess the potential role of these beliefs, we ask the third-party participants, in the third and final question, to predict the percent of male/female workers who voluntarily choose to negotiate in the setting detailed to them in the second question. The third-party participants had to indicate whether they believed that 010%, 11-20%, 21-30%, ..., or 91%-100% of male/female workers choose to negotiate. If the third question is selected as the question that counts for payments, third-party participants receive an additional 50 cents in bonus payment if their prediction is correct and no bonus payment if their prediction is incorrect. We find that third-party participants believe that male workers negotiate more frequently than female workers (58.06% vs 50.50%, two-sided t-test, p < 0.01), however, Column 3 of Table 7 shows that the greater willingness to restrict a woman’s negotiation 28 decision persists and, if anything, strengthens when we control for the belief that the individual negotiates.39 If increased negotiations are costly in this setting, the greater tendency to push women to negotiate will impose a greater cost on women. To examine whether increased negotiations are costly in this setting, our first-party experiment involves negotiation opportunities between workers and firms like those described in the third-party experiment. The results in the firstparty experiment replicate our main findings from the laboratory experiment (see Appendix A.6 for details): workers choose to frequently avoid negotiations (68% of the time in this case) and this avoidance is not to their detriment. Increased negotiations are neither helpful to women nor to men nor are they more helpful to women than they are to men. If anything, increased negotiations are more harmful to women than they are to men. To summarize, these two additional experiments examine a setting where workers choose to avoid the majority of negotiation opportunities and where workers are significantly worse off financially if they do not have the opportunity to avoid negotiations. Finding that thirdparty participants are willing to pay to prevent workers from having the opportunity to avoid negotiations thus implies that they make workers worse off both from a revealed preference standpoint and from a financial standpoint. Third-party participants’ greater willingness to pay to prevent female than male workers from having the opportunity to avoid negotiations further implies that female workers are more likely to suffer the consequences of such financially harmful and paternalistic decisions than male workers are. Indeed, while Appendix A.6 shows that the cost of always negotiating is 17 percent greater, but insignificantly so, for women than for men, this difference is magnified when including the third party’s decision to restrict the worker’s negotiation decision. With women more frequently being pushed to negotiate, the cost imposed on women is twice that of men (p=0.048). Thus, the introduction of a third-party “guidance” is more costly for women than it is for men. 7 Conclusion Results related to the negotiation literature fall into one of two strands. The first strand abstracts away from the decision to enter negotiations and investigates what characteristics of the environment influence negotiation outcomes when negotiations are required. In relation to this first strand, we find that individuals achieve substantially and significantly better profits from negotiations as the bonus decreases. That is, individuals are more successful at securing more than their suggested wage when their suggested wage falls short of what they contribute to joint revenue. The second strand investigates what factors influence the negotiation-entry decisions and the outcomes conditional on entering negotiations. In relation to this second 39 A participant’s belief is estimated as the midpoint of the percentage range they selected as being most likely in terms of the percent of male/female workers who will choose to enter a negotiation. For instance, if they indicated that they believe 11-20% of male workers would enter a negotiation, their belief measure equals 15. 29 strand, we observe evidence that is consistent with positive selection: individuals are more likely to enter negotiations as the bonus decreases and thus as profits from negotiations are generally higher. In relation to the gender literature on both of these strands, we mostly do not observe significant gender differences in negotiation outcomes.40 This is not surprising given that we used prior literature to guide our design decisions such that gender differences were expected to be minimal. This paper distinguishes itself by addressing a question distinct from these two strands of the literature. We ask whether individuals — and specifically whether women in light of the lean-in advice that is targeted at them — would financially benefit from negotiating more often in an environment where they (i) generally secure positive profits in the negotiations they choose to enter but (ii) frequently avoid negotiations. We ask this question because its answer is not simply yes. The fact that individuals who choose to negotiate in select situations largely benefit from doing so does not imply that all individuals should negotiate all of the time. Understanding how individuals select into negotiations and what they would achieve from negotiations that they choose to avoid is crucial. We also note that a non-trivial answer to this question requires an environment where losses from negotiations are possible.41 Thus, to answer whether individuals would financially benefit from negotiating more often, we conduct a laboratory experiment that provides the first comparison of outcomes from a setting where individuals choose whether to negotiate to the counterfactual outcomes from a setting where individuals always negotiate. In particular, we examine how outcomes differ when individuals can select into negotiations in our Choice (of negotiation) treatment to when they always negotiate in our Always (negotiate) treatment. Our corresponding results, which we replicate at a different university with a larger sample, provide a clear caution to lean-in advice targeted towards women While women largely gain when they choose to negotiate in the Choice treatment, increased negotiations in the Always treatment do not result in any additional gains for women. When given a choice, women enter negotiations that are financially beneficial and frequently avoid negotiations that are financially harmful. Indeed, women positively select into negotiations and forcing women to negotiate hurts them. We find that increased negotiations are not more helpful, or less harmful, to women than they are to men. As supported by our additional online experiments, higher costs to women may further arise due to a greater paternalistic demand for preventing women, more so than men, from avoiding negotiations. 40 The slight gender differences we observe in our initial Stanford experiment, but not in our Pittsburgh experiment, are as follows. In the Always treatment, negotiations by men are less likely to result in losses. In the Choice treatment, negotiations by men are more likely to result in losses and men are more likely to enter negotiations. 41 In environments where negotiations always result in weakly positive profits, it follows the negotiating more often is weakly financially beneficial. 30 Investigating when a misguided desire for increased negotiations arises, particularly one directed disproportionately towards women, is an interesting avenue for future work. Determining if and when increased negotiations would instead benefit women is also an important avenue for future work.42 In regard to this latter avenue, we note that exploring factors known to drive gender differences in negotiation outcomes, factors that our design purposefully eliminated, may prove fruitful. For instance, women may shy away from financially beneficial negotiations if they undervalue what they bring to the table because — unlike in our study — they may neither know their individual contributions nor their outside options. Even in these cases, however, one should be wary of blanket recommendations to women that they should negotiate more often. 42 One approach is to consider interventions that seek to bolster women’s negotiation skills. For instance, using the well-cited statistics that women earn less than men as motivation (Blau and Kahn, 2016), the United States Department of Labor encourages women to “aim higher and negotiate better” (see https://blog.dol.gov/2015/04/13/its-time-for-equal-pay-now). The Paycheck Fairness Act, a proposed amendment to the Equal Pay Act, even includes a provision that authorizes the Secretary of Labor “to make grants to eligible entities for negotiation skills training programs for girls and women.” (see https://www.congress.gov/bill/114th-congress/house-bill/1619.) With the goal of helping to close the wage gap, universities and companies provide negotiation workshops, such as those via the Program for Research and Outreach on Gender Equity in Society at Carnegie Mellon University (see http://progress.heinz.cmu.edu/about-us). 31 References Almås, Ingvild, Alexander W...
Purchase answer to see full attachment
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following Studypool's honor code & terms of service.

Explanation & Answer

Hey fam'Here you go kindly check it out and feel free to invite me for more questions

EVALUATION

1

Evaluation Of The Cost Of Leaning-in.
Course:
Professor:
Due date:

EVALUATION

2

It is not a mistake sometimes to lean out.
This research seeks to find out if women usually negotiate their salaries. The respondents
are both men and women, they respond through chat messages that are anonymous.
According to the research "Women Who Don't Negotiate Might Have a Good Reason ",
it clear that it is sometimes not a mistake to choose to lean out. After the research, studies
show that among the ones who had a choice treatment and those who experienced a
forced treatment the wise ones were those who sometimes chose not to go through the
negotiations. This is because they would normally undergo a benefit financially. From
research, the wages normally decreased once the women had to be forced to involve
themselves in negotiations. This was as a result of the final wages. The same rate of the
wage was seen to be paid when negotiations were done and when negotiations were
chosen to be avoided (Exley, et.al pp. 6)
Women have a choice on choosing whether they should lean in.
The research denotes that women have to be considered to be such good judges,
to have to decide on whether they should choose to lean in or should choose not to lean
in. Women who choose to enter into negotiations have been found to gain from
negotiating. However, this cannot be put into conclusion that each and every woman
should always choose to get into negotiations despite the fact that those who do
eventually gain. Choosing to avoid negotiations can be so a place most commonly, costly
circumstances are in the long run avoided. In most cases, there are backfires when
negotiations arise, hence it is advisable that a better approach is put into consideration.
This may include having to require more advanced skills in the process of negotiations.

EVALUATION

3

Individuals also should set aside enough quality time to be able to assess well the offer
they choose to bring forward. This, therefore, leads to a conclusion that in some cases it
is always better not to involve oneself into negotiations.
According to the research "Knowing When to Ask: The Cost of Leaning-in", it is
evident that women normally know when to get themselves into negotiations which is
contrary to men. It is from a common fact that women in most instances, try to avoid
getting into negotiations in a choice treatment. They normally have a choice to get into
negotiations that finally ends up to them gaining. They also have a choice to avoid
negotiations, especially when they see the negotiations may result in them losing. When
women are forced into negotiations it normally leads to them getting hurt. This suggests
that even though negotiations benefit women financially, women always never neg...


Anonymous
Really helpful material, saved me a great deal of time.

Studypool
4.7
Trustpilot
4.5
Sitejabber
4.4

Related Tags