page 515
PART FIVE: SPECIAL TOPICS
Options and
Corporate Finance
17
OPENING
CASE
On March 31, 2016, the closing stock prices for Reynolds
American, Cabela’s, and Royal Gold were $50.31, $48.69, and
$51.29, respectively. Each company had a call option trading on
the Chicago Board Options Exchange with a $55 strike price and
an expiration date of May 20—50 days away. Given how close
the stock prices are, you might expect that the prices on these
call options would be similar, but they were not. The Reynolds
American options sold for $.15, Cabela’s options traded at $.95,
and Royal Gold options traded at $1.69. Why would options on
these three similarly priced stocks be priced so differently when
the strike prices and the time to expiration were exactly the
same? A big reason is that the volatility of the underlying stock is
an important determinant of an option’s underlying value, and in
fact, these three stocks had very different volatilities. In this
chapter, we will explore this issue—and many others—in much
greater depth using the Nobel prize-winning Black-Scholes option
929
pricing model.
Please visit us at corecorporatefinance.blogspot.com for the latest developments in
the world of corporate finance.
17.1 OPTIONS
An option is a contract giving its owner the right to buy or sell an asset at
a fixed price on or before a given date. For example, an option on a
building might give the buyer the right to buy the building for $1 million
on or anytime before the Saturday prior to the third Wednesday in January
2018. Options are a unique type of financial contract because they give the
buyer the right, but not the obligation, to do something. The buyer uses the
option only if it is advantageous to do so; otherwise the option can be
thrown away.
The Options Industry Council has a web page with lots of educational material at
www.optionseducation.org.
There is a special vocabulary associated with options. Here are some
important definitions:
1. Exercising the option. The act of buying or selling the underlying
asset via the option contract is referred to as exercising the option.
2. Strike or exercise price. The fixed price in the option contract at
which the holder can buy or sell the underlying asset is called the
strike price or exercise price.
3. Expiration date. The maturity date of the option is referred to as the
expiration date. After this date, the option is dead.
4. American and European options. An American option may be
exercised anytime up to the expiration date. A European option
differs from an American option in that it can be exercised only on
the expiration date.
page 516
17.2 CALL OPTIONS
930
The most common type of option is a call option. A call option gives the
owner the right to buy an asset at a fixed price during a particular time
period. There is no restriction on the kind of asset, but the most common
ones traded on exchanges are options on stocks and bonds.
For example, call options on IBM stock can be purchased on the
Chicago Board Options Exchange. IBM does not issue (that is, sell) call
options on its common stock. Instead, individual investors are the original
buyers and sellers of call options on IBM common stock. A representative
call option on IBM stock enables an investor to buy 100 shares of IBM on
or before July 15, at an exercise price of $100. This is a valuable option if
there is some probability that the price of IBM common stock will exceed
$100 on or before July 15.
The Value of a Call Option at Expiration
What is the value of a call option contract on common stock at expiration?
The answer depends on the value of the underlying stock at expiration.
Let’s continue with the IBM example. Suppose the stock price is $130
at expiration. The buyer1 of the call option has the right to buy the
underlying stock at the exercise price of $100. In other words, he has the
right to exercise the call. Having the right to buy something for $100 when
it is worth $130 is obviously a good thing. The value of this right is $30 (=
$130 − 100) on the expiration day.2
The call would be worth even more if the stock price were higher on
expiration day. For example, if IBM were selling for $150 on the date of
expiration, the call would be worth $50 (= $150 − 100) at that time. In
fact, the call’s value increases $1 for every $1 rise in the stock price.
If the stock price is greater than the exercise price, we say that the call
is in the money. Of course, it is also possible that the value of the common
stock will turn out to be less than the exercise price. In this case, we say
that the call is out of the money. The holder will not exercise in this case.
For example, if the stock price at the expiration date is $90, no rational
investor would exercise. Why pay $100 for stock worth only $90? Because
the option holder has no obligation to exercise the call, she can walk away
from the option. As a consequence, if IBM’s stock price is less than $100
on the expiration date, the value of the call option will be $0. In this case,
the value of the call option is not the difference between IBM’s stock price
and $100, as it would be if the holder of the call option had the obligation
to exercise the call.
The payoff of a call option at expiration is:
931
PAYOFF ON THE EXPIRATION DATE
IF STOCK PRICE IS
LESS THAN $100
IF STOCK PRICE IS
GREATER THAN $100
$0
Stock price − $100
Call option value
Figure 17.1 plots the value of the call at expiration against the value of
IBM’s stock. It is referred to as the hockey stick diagram of call option
values. If the stock price is less than $100, the call is out of the money and
worthless. If the stock price is greater than $100, the call is
page 517
in the money and its value rises one-for-one with increases
in the stock price. Notice that the call can never have a negative value. It is
a limited liability instrument, which means that all the holder can lose is
the initial amount she paid for it.
FIGURE 17.1
The Value of a Call Option on the Expiration Date
EXAMPLE
17.1
Call Option Payoffs
Suppose Mr. Optimist holds a one-year call option on TIX common
stock. It is a European call option and can be exercised at $150.
Assume that the expiration date has arrived. What is the value of the
932
TIX call option on the expiration date? If TIX is selling for $200 per
share, Mr. Optimist can exercise the option—purchase TIX at $150—
and then immediately sell the share at $200. Mr. Optimist will have
made $50 (= $200 − 150).
Instead, assume that TIX is selling for $100 per share on the
expiration date. If Mr. Optimist still holds the call option, he will throw it
out. The value of the TIX call on the expiration date will be $0 in this
case.
17.3 PUT OPTIONS
A put option can be viewed as the opposite of a call option. Just as a call
gives the holder the right to buy the stock at a fixed price, a put gives the
holder the right to sell the stock for a fixed exercise price.
The Value of a Put Option at Expiration
The circumstances that determine the value of the put are the opposite of
those for a call option, because a put option gives the holder the right to
sell shares. Let us assume that the exercise price of the put is $50 and the
stock price at expiration is $40. The owner of this put option has the right
to sell the stock for more than it is worth, something that is clearly
profitable. That is, he can buy the stock at the market price of $40 and
immediately sell it at the exercise price of $50, generating a profit of $10
(= $50 − 40). Thus, the value of the option at expiration must be $10.
page 518
FIGURE 17.2
The Value of a Put Option on the Expiration Date
933
The profit would be greater still if the stock price were lower. For
example, if the stock price were only $30, the value of the option would be
$20 (= $50 − 30). In fact, for every $1 that the stock price declines at
expiration, the value of the put rises by $1.
However, suppose that the stock at expiration is trading at $60—or any
price above the exercise price of $50. The owner of the put would not want
to exercise here. It is a losing proposition to sell stock for $50 when it
trades in the open market at $60. Instead, the owner of the put will walk
away from the option. That is, he will let the put option expire.
The payoff of this put option is:
PAYOFF ON THE EXPIRATION DATE
Put option value
IF STOCK PRICE IS
LESS THAN $50
IF STOCK PRICE IS
GREATER THAN $50
$50 − Stock price
$0
Figure 17.2 plots the values of a put option for all possible values of the
underlying stock. It is instructive to compare Figure 17.2 with Figure 17.1
for the call option. The call option is valuable whenever the stock is above
the exercise price, and the put is valuable when the stock price is below the
exercise price.
EXAMPLE
17.2
934
Put Option Payoffs
Ms. Pessimist feels quite certain that BMI will fall from its current $160
per-share price. She buys a put. Her put option contract gives her the
right to sell a share of BMI stock at $150 one year from now. If the price
of BMI is $200 on the expiration date, she will tear up the put option
contract because it is worthless. That is, she will not want to sell stock
worth $200 for the exercise price of $150.
On the other hand, if BMI is selling for $100 on the expiration date,
she will exercise the option. In this case, she can buy a share of BMI in
the market for $100 per share and turn around and sell the share at the
exercise price of $150. Her profit will be $50 (= $150 − 100). The value
of the put option on the expiration date therefore will be $50.
page 519
17.4 SELLING OPTIONS
An investor who sells (or writes) a call on common stock promises to
deliver shares of the common stock if required to do so by the call option
holder. Notice that the seller is obligated to do so.
Check out this option exchange: www.cmegroup.com.
If, at the expiration date, the price of the common stock is greater than
the exercise price, the holder will exercise the call and the seller must give
the holder shares of stock in exchange for the exercise price. The seller
loses the difference between the stock price and the exercise price. For
example, assume that the stock price is $60 and the exercise price is $50.
Knowing that exercise is imminent, the option seller buys stock in the
open market at $60. Because she is obligated to sell at $50, she loses $10
(= $50 − 60). Conversely, if at the expiration date, the price of the
common stock is below the exercise price, the call option will not be
exercised and the seller’s liability is zero.
Why would the seller of a call place himself in such a precarious
position? After all, the seller loses money if the stock price ends up above
the exercise price and he merely avoids losing money if the stock price
935
ends up below the exercise price. The answer is that the seller is paid to
take this risk. On the day that the option transaction takes place, the seller
receives the price that the buyer pays.
Now, let’s look at the seller of puts. An investor who sells a put on
common stock agrees to purchase shares of common stock if the put holder
should so request. The seller loses on this deal if the stock price falls
below the exercise price and the holder puts the stock to the seller. For
example, assume that the stock price is $40 and the exercise price is $50.
The holder of the put will exercise in this case. In other words, he will sell
the underlying stock at the exercise price of $50. This means that the seller
of the put must buy the underlying stock at the exercise price of $50.
Because the stock is only worth $40, the loss here is $10 (= $40 − 50).
The values of the “sell-a-call” and “sell-a-put” positions are depicted in
Figure 17.3. The graph on the left-hand side of the figure shows that the
seller of a call loses nothing when the stock price at expiration is below
$50. However, the seller loses a dollar for every dollar that the stock rises
above $50. The graph in the center of the figure shows that the seller of a
put loses nothing when the stock price at the expiration date is above $50.
However, the seller loses a dollar for every dollar that the stock falls below
$50.
FIGURE 17.3
The Payoffs to Sellers of Calls and Puts and Buyers of Common Stock
It is worthwhile to spend a few minutes comparing the graphs in Figure
17.3 to those in Figures 17.1 and 17.2. The graph of selling a call (the
graph in the left-hand side of Figure 17.3) is the mirror image of the graph
page 520
of buying a call (Figure 17.1).3 This occurs because options
are a zero-sum game. The seller of a call loses what the
buyer makes. Similarly, the graph of selling a put (the middle graph in
Figure 17.3) is the mirror image of the graph of buying a put (Figure 17.2).
936
Again, the seller of a put loses what the buyer makes.
Figure 17.3 also shows the value at expiration of simply buying
common stock. Notice that buying the stock is the same as buying a call
option on the stock with an exercise price of $0. This is not surprising. If
the exercise price is $0, the call holder can buy the stock for nothing,
which is really the same as owning it.
17.5 OPTION QUOTES
Now that we understand the definitions for calls and puts, let’s see how
these options are quoted. Table 17.1 presents information on Intel
Corporation options expiring in April 2016, obtained from
finance.yahoo.com. At the time of these quotes, Intel was selling for
$32.45.
For more on option ticker symbols, go to the “Symbol Directory” link under
“Trading Resources” at www.cboe.com.
TABLE 17.1
Information on the options of Intel Corporation
937
On the left-hand side of the table are the available strike prices. The
top half of the table presents call option quotes; put option quotes are
featured in the section below. The second column contains
page 521
ticker symbols, which uniquely indicate the underlying
stock, the type of option, the expiration date, and the strike price. Next, we
have the most recent prices on the options (“Last”), the bid and ask prices,
and the change from the previous day (“Change”). Note that option prices
are quoted on a per-option basis, but trading actually occurs in
standardized contracts, where each contract calls for the purchase (for
938
calls) or sale (for puts) of 100 shares. Thus, the call option with a strike
price of $33 last traded at $1.09 per option, or $109 per contract. Volume
shows the number of contracts traded this day, and Open Interest is the
number of contracts currently outstanding.
17.6 COMBINATIONS OF OPTIONS
Puts and calls can serve as building blocks for more complex option
contracts. For example, Figure 17.4 illustrates the payoff from buying a
put option on a stock and simultaneously buying the stock.
ExcelMaster coverage online
www.mhhe.com/RossCore5e
If the share price is greater than the exercise price, the put option is
worthless, and the value of the combined position is equal to the value of
the common stock. If instead the exercise price is greater than the share
price, the decline in the value of the shares will be exactly offset by the
rise in value of the put.
The strategy of buying a put and buying the underlying stock is called
a protective put. It is as if one is buying insurance for the stock. The stock
can always be sold at the exercise price, regardless of how far the market
price of the stock falls.
Note that the combination of buying a put and buying the underlying
stock has the same shape in Figure 17.4 as the call purchase in Figure
17.1. To pursue this point, let’s consider the graph for buying a call, which
is shown at the far left of Figure 17.5.
FIGURE 17.4
Payoff to the Combination of Buying a Put and Buying the Underlying
Stock
939
FIGURE 17.5
Payoff to the Combination of Buying a Call and Buying a Zero Coupon
Bond
page 522
This graph is the same as Figure 17.1, except that the exercise price is $50
here. Now let’s try the strategy of:
(Leg A) Buying a call.
(Leg B) Buying a risk-free, zero coupon bond (i.e., a T-bill), with a face value of $50
that matures on the same day that the option expires.
We have drawn the graph of Leg A of this strategy at the far left of
Figure 17.5, but what does the graph of Leg B look like? It looks like the
middle graph of the figure. That is, anyone buying this zero coupon bond
will be guaranteed to get $50, regardless of the price of the stock at
expiration.
What does the graph of simultaneously buying both Leg A and Leg B
of this strategy look like? It looks like the far-right graph of Figure 17.5.
That is, the investor receives a guaranteed $50 from the bond, regardless of
what happens to the stock. In addition, the investor receives a payoff from
the call of $1 for every $1 that the price of the stock rises above the
exercise price of $50.
The far-right graph of Figure 17.5 looks exactly like the far-right graph
of Figure 17.4. Thus, an investor gets the same payoff from the strategy of
Figure 17.4 and the strategy of Figure 17.5, regardless of what happens to
the price of the underlying stock. In other words, the investor gets the
same payoff from:
1. Buying a put and buying the underlying stock.
2. Buying a call and buying a risk-free, zero coupon bond.
940
If investors have the same payoffs from the two strategies, the two
strategies must have the same cost. Otherwise, all investors will choose the
strategy with the lower cost and avoid the strategy with the higher cost.
This leads to the interesting result that:
This relationship is known as put–call parity and is one of the most
fundamental relationships concerning options. It says that there are two
ways of buying a protective put. You can buy a put and buy the underlying
stock simultaneously. Here, your total cost is the price of the underlying
stock plus the price of the put. Or, you can buy a call and buy a zero
coupon bond. Here, your total cost is the price of the call plus the price of
the zero coupon bond. The price of the zero coupon bond is equal to the
present value of the exercise price, i.e., the present value of $50 in our
example.
Equation 17.1 is a very precise relationship. It holds only if the put and
the call have both the same exercise price and the same expiration date. In
addition, the maturity date of the zero coupon bond must be the same as
the expiration date of the options.
To see how fundamental put–call parity is, let’s rearrange the formula,
yielding:
This relationship now states that you can replicate the purchase of a
share of stock by buying a call, selling a put, and buying a zero coupon
bond. (Note that, because a minus sign comes before “Price of put,” the
put is sold, not bought.) Investors in this three-legged strategy are said to
have purchased a synthetic stock.
Let’s do one more transformation:
page 523
FIGURE 17.6
Payoff to the Combination of Buying a Stock and Selling a Call
941
Many investors like to buy a stock and write a call on the stock
simultaneously. This is a conservative strategy known as selling a covered
call. The preceding put–call parity relationship tells us that this strategy is
equivalent to selling a put and buying a zero coupon bond. Figure 17.6
develops the graph for the covered call. You can verify that the covered
call can be replicated by selling a put and simultaneously buying a zero
coupon bond.
Of course, there are other ways of rearranging the basic put–call
relationship. For each rearrangement, the strategy on the left-hand side is
equivalent to the strategy on the right-hand side. The beauty of put–call
parity is that it shows how any strategy in options can be achieved in two
different ways.
To test your understanding of put–call parity, suppose shares of stock
in Joseph-Belmont, Inc., are selling for $80. A three-month call option
with an $85 strike price goes for $6. The risk-free rate is .5 percent per
month. What’s the value of a three-month put option with an $85 strike
price?
We can rearrange the put–call parity relationship to solve for the price
of the put as follows:
As illustrated, the value of the put is $9.74.
EXAMPLE
17.3
A Synthetic T-bill
942
Suppose that shares of stock in Smolira Corp. are selling for $110. A
call option on Smolira with one year to maturity and a $110 strike price
sells for $15. A put with the same terms sells for $5. What’s the risk-free
rate?
To answer, we need to use put–call parity to determine the price of a
risk-free, zero coupon bond:
Plugging in the numbers, we get:
Since the present value of the $110 strike price is $100, the implied
risk-free rate is obviously 10 percent.
page 524
17.7 VALUING OPTIONS
In the last section, we determined what options are worth on the expiration
date. Now, we wish to determine the value of options when you buy them
well before expiration.4 We begin by considering the lower and upper
bounds on the value of a call.
Bounding the Value of a Call
LOWER BOUND Consider an American call that is in the money prior
to expiration. For example, assume that the stock price is $60 and the
exercise price is $50. In this case, the option cannot sell below $10. To see
this, note the simple strategy if the option sells at, say, $9.
DATE
TRANSACTION
Today
(1)
Buy call.
−$ 9
Today
(2)
Exercise call—that is, buy
underlying stock at
exercise price.
−$50
+$60
Today
(3)
Sell stock at current
+$ 1
943
market price.
Arbitrage profit
The type of profit that is described in this transaction is an arbitrage profit.
Arbitrage profits come from transactions that have no risk or cost and
cannot occur regularly in normal, well-functioning financial markets. The
excess demand for these options would quickly force the option price up to
at least $10 (= $60 − 50).
Of course, the price of the option is likely to be above $10. Investors
will rationally pay more than $10 because of the possibility that the stock
will rise above $60 before expiration. For example, suppose the call
actually sells for $12. In this case, we say that the intrinsic value of the
option is $10, meaning it must always be worth at least this much. The
remaining $12 − 10 = $2 is sometimes called the time premium, and it
represents the extra that investors are willing to pay because of the
possibility that the stock price will rise before the option expires.
UPPER BOUND Is there an upper boundary for the option price as
well? It turns out that the upper boundary is the price of the underlying
stock. That is, an option to buy common stock cannot have a greater value
than the common stock itself. A call option can be used to buy common
stock with a payment of an exercise price. It would be foolish to buy stock
this way if the stock could be purchased directly at a lower price.
The upper and lower bounds are represented in Figure 17.7. In
addition, these bounds are summarized in the bottom half of Table 17.2.
The Factors Determining Call Option Values
The previous discussion indicated that the price of a call option must fall
somewhere in the shaded region of Figure 17.7. We now will determine
more precisely where in the shaded region it should be. The factors that
determine a call’s value can be broken into two sets. The first set contains
the features of the option contract. The two basic contractual features are
the expiration date and the exercise price. The second set of factors
affecting the call price concerns characteristics of the stock and the market.
EXERCISE PRICE An increase in the exercise price reduces the value
of the call. For example, imagine that there are two calls on a stock selling
at $60. The first call has an exercise price of $50 and the page 525
second one has an exercise price of $40. Which call would you
944
rather have? Clearly, you would rather have the call with an exercise price
of $40, because that one is $20 (= $60 − 40) in the money. In other words,
the call with an exercise price of $40 should sell for more than an
otherwise identical call with an exercise price of $50.
FIGURE 17.7
The Upper and Lower Boundaries of Call Option Values
TABLE 17.2
Factors Affecting American Option Values
CALL
OPTION*
PUT
OPTION*
Value of underlying asset (stock
price)
+
−
Exercise price
−
+
Stock volatility
+
+
Interest rate
+
−
Time to expiration date
+
+
INCREASE IN
In addition to the preceding, we have presented the following four
relationships for American calls:
1. The call price can never be greater than the stock price (upper
bound).
2. The call price can never be less than either zero or the difference
945
between the stock price and the exercise price (lower bound).
3. The call is worth zero if the stock is worth zero.
4. When the stock price is much greater than the exercise price, the call
price tends toward the difference between the stock price and the
present value of the exercise price.
* The signs (+, −) indicate the effect of the variables on the value of the option. For example, the
two +s for stock volatility Indicate that an increase in volatility will increase both the value of a call
and the value of a put.
EXPIRATION DATE The value of an American call option must be at
least as great as the value of an otherwise identical option with a shorter
term to expiration. Consider two American calls: One has a maturity of
nine months and the other expires in six months. Obviously, the ninemonth call has the same rights as the six-month call, and it also has an
additional three months within which these rights can be exercised. It
cannot be worth less and will generally be more valuable.5
STOCK PRICE Other things being equal, the higher the stock price, the
more valuable the call option will be. For example, if a stock is worth $80,
a call with an exercise price of $100 isn’t worth very much. If the stock
soars to $120, the call becomes much more valuable.
page 526
FIGURE 17.8
Value of an American Call as a Function of Stock Price
946
Now consider Figure 17.8, which shows the relationship between the
call price and the stock price prior to expiration. The curve indicates that
the call price increases as the stock price increases. Furthermore, it can be
shown that the relationship is represented, not by a straight line, but by a
convex curve. That is, the increase in the call price for a given change in
the stock price is greater when the stock price is high than when the stock
price is low.
There are two special items of note regarding the curve in Figure 17.8:
1. The Stock Is Worthless. The call must be worthless if the underlying
stock is worthless. That is, if the stock has no chance of attaining any
value, it is not worthwhile to pay the exercise price in order to obtain
the stock.
2. The Stock Price Is Very High Relative to the Exercise Price. In this
situation, the owner of the call knows that he will end up exercising
the call. He can view himself as the owner of the stock now, with one
difference. He must pay the exercise price at expiration.
Thus, the value of his position, i.e., the value of the call, is:
These two points are summarized in the bottom half of Table 17.2.
THE KEY FACTOR: THE VARIABILITY OF THE UNDERLYING
ASSET The greater the variability of the underlying asset, the more
valuable the call option will be. Consider the following example. Suppose
that just before the call expires, the stock price will be either $100 with
probability .5 or $80 with probability .5. What will be the value of a call
with an exercise price of $110? Clearly, it will be worthless because no
matter what happens to the stock, its price will always be below the
exercise price.
For an option-oriented site focusing on volatilities, visit www.ivolatility.com.
Now let us see what happens if the stock is more variable. Suppose that
we add $20 to the best case and take $20 away from the worst case. Now
the stock has a one-half chance of being worth $60 and a one-half chance
of being worth $120. We have spread the stock returns, but, of course, the
expected value of the stock has stayed the same:
947
Notice that the call option has value now because there is a one-half
chance that the stock price will be $120, or $10 above the exercise price of
$110. This illustrates a very important point. There is a fundamental
distinction between holding an option on an underlying asset and holding
the underlying asset. If investors in the marketplace are risk-averse, a rise
in the variability of the stock will decrease its market value.
page 527
However, the holder of a call receives payoffs from the
positive tail of the probability distribution. As a consequence, a rise in the
variability in the underlying stock increases the market value of the call.
FIGURE 17.9
Distribution of Common Stock Price at Expiration for Both Security A and
Security B. Options on the Two Securities Have the Same Exercise Price.
This result can also be seen in Figure 17.9. Consider two stocks, A and
B, each of which is normally distributed. For each security, the figure
illustrates the probability of different stock prices on the expiration date.6
As can be seen from the figure, Stock B has more volatility than does
Stock A. This means that Stock B has a higher probability of both
abnormally high returns and abnormally low returns. Let us assume that
options on each of the two securities have the same exercise price. To
option holders, a return much below average on Stock B is no worse than a
return only moderately below average on Stock A. In either situation, the
option expires out of the money. However, to option holders, a return
948
much above average on Stock B is better than a return only moderately
above average on Stock A. Because a call’s price at the expiration date is
the difference between the stock price and the exercise price, the value of
the call on B at expiration will be higher in this case.
THE INTEREST RATE Call prices are also a function of the level of
interest rates. Buyers of calls do not pay the exercise price until they
exercise the option, if they do so at all. The ability to delay payment is
more valuable when interest rates are high and less valuable when interest
rates are low. Thus, the value of a call is positively related to interest rates.
A Quick Discussion of Factors Determining Put
Option Values
Given our extended discussion of the factors influencing a call’s value, we
can examine the effect of these factors on puts very easily. Table 17.2
summarizes the five factors influencing the prices of both American calls
and American puts. The effect of three factors on puts is the opposite of
the effect of these three factors on calls:
1. Value of Underlying Asset. The put’s market value decreases as the
stock price increases because puts are in the money when the stock
sells below the exercise price.
2. Exercise Price. The value of a put with a high exercise price is
greater than the value of an otherwise identical put with a low
exercise price for the reason given in (1).
3. Interest Rate. A high interest rate adversely affects the
page 528
value of a put. The ability to sell a stock at a fixed
exercise price sometime in the future is worth less if the present value
of the exercise price is diminished by a high interest rate.
The effect of the other two factors on puts is the same as the effect of these
factors on calls:
4. Time to Expiration Date. The value of an American put with a distant
expiration date is greater than an otherwise identical put with an
earlier expiration.7 The longer time to maturity gives the put holder
more flexibility, just as it did in the case of a call.
5. Stock Volatility. Volatility of the underlying stock increases the value
of the put. The reasoning is analogous to that for a call. At expiration,
949
a put that is way in the money is more valuable than a put only
slightly in the money. However, at expiration, a put way out of the
money is worth zero, just as is a put only slightly out of the money.
17.8 AN OPTION PRICING FORMULA
We have explained qualitatively that the value of a call option is a function
of five variables:
ExcelMaster coverage online
www.mhhe.com/RossCore5e
1. The current price of the underlying asset, which for stock options is
the price of a share of common stock.
2. The exercise price.
3. The time to expiration date.
4. The variance of the underlying asset’s rate of return.
5. The risk-free interest rate.
It is time to replace the qualitative model with a precise option
valuation model. The model we choose is the famous Black–Scholes
option pricing model. You can put numbers into the Black–Scholes model
and get values back.
The Black–Scholes model is represented by a rather imposing formula.
A derivation of the formula is simply not practical in this textbook, as
many students will be happy to learn. However, some appreciation for the
achievement as well as some intuitive understanding is in order.
In the early chapters of this book, we showed how to discount capital
budgeting projects using the net present value formula. We also used this
approach to value stocks and bonds. Why, students sometimes ask, can’t
the same NPV formula be used to value puts and calls? It is a good
question because the earliest attempts at valuing options used NPV.
Unfortunately, the attempts were simply not successful because no one
could determine the appropriate discount rate. An option is generally
riskier than the underlying stock, but no one knew exactly how much
riskier.
Fischer Black and Myron Scholes attacked the problem by pointing out
that a strategy of borrowing to finance a stock purchase duplicates the risk
of a call. Then, knowing the price of a stock already, one can determine
950
the price of a call such that its return is identical to that of the stock-withborrowing alternative.
We illustrate the intuition behind the Black–Scholes approach by
considering a simple example where a combination of a call and a stock
eliminates all risk. This example works because we let the future stock
price be one of only two values. Hence, the example is called a two-state
option model. By eliminating the possibility that the stock price can take
on other values, we are able to duplicate the call exactly.
page 529
A Two-State Option Model
Consider the following example. Suppose the current market price of a
stock is $50 and the stock will sell for either $60 or $40 at the end of the
year. Further, imagine a call option on this stock with a one-year
expiration date and a $50 exercise price. Investors can borrow at 10
percent. Our goal is to determine the value of the call.
In order to value the call correctly, we need to examine two strategies.
The first is to simply buy the call. The second is to:
a. Buy one-half a share of stock.
b. Borrow $18.18, implying a payment of principal and interest at the
end of the year of $20 (= $18.18 × 1.10).
As you will see shortly, the cash flows from the second strategy exactly
match the cash flows from buying a call. (A little later, we will show how
we came up with the exact fraction of a share of stock to buy and the exact
borrowing amount.) Because the cash flows match, we say that we are
duplicating the call with the second strategy.
At the end of the year, the future payoffs are set out as follows:
FUTURE PAYOFFS
INITIAL TRANSACTIONS
$60 − 50 = $10
1. Buy a call
2. Buy
IF STOCK PRICE IS
$60
× $60 = $30
share of stock
Borrow $18.18 at 10%
−($18.18 × 1.10) = −$20
951
Total from stock and borrowing strategy
$10
Note that the future payoff structure of the “buy-a-call” strategy is
duplicated by the strategy of “buy stock” and “borrow.” That is, under
either strategy, an investor would end up with $10 if the stock price rose
and $0 if the stock price fell. Thus, these two strategies are equivalent as
far as traders are concerned.
Now, if two strategies always have the same cash flows at the end of
the year, how must their initial costs be related? The two strategies must
have the same initial cost. Otherwise, there will be an arbitrage possibility.
We can easily calculate this cost for our strategy of buying stock and
borrowing. This cost is:
Buy
share of stock
Borrow $18.18
× $50 =
$25.00
− 18.18
$ 6.82
Because the call option provides the same payoffs at expiration as does
the strategy of buying stock and borrowing, the call must be priced at
$6.82. This is the value of the call option in a market without arbitrage
profits.
We left two issues unexplained in the preceding example.
DETERMINING THE DELTA How did we know to buy one-half a
share of stock in the duplicating strategy? Actually, the answer is easier
than it might at first appear. The call price at the end of the year will be
either $10 or $0, whereas the stock price will be either $60 or $40. Thus,
the call price has a potential swing of $10 (= $10 − 0) next period, whereas
the stock price has a potential swing of $20 (= $60 − 40). We can write
this in terms of the following ratio:
page 530
As indicated, this ratio is called the delta of the call. In words, a $1 swing
in the price of the stock gives rise to a $1/2 swing in the price of the call.
Because we are trying to duplicate the call with the stock, it seems sensible
to buy one-half a share of stock instead of buying one call. In other words,
952
the risk of buying one-half a share of stock should be the same as the risk
of buying one call.
DETERMINING THE AMOUNT OF BORROWING How did we
know how much to borrow? Buying one-half a share of stock brings us
either $30 or $20 at expiration, which is exactly $20 more than the payoffs
of $10 and $0, respectively, from the call. To duplicate the call through a
purchase of stock, we should also borrow enough money so that we have
to pay back exactly $20 of interest and principal. This amount of
borrowing is merely the present value of $20, which is $18.18 (=
$20/1.10).
Now that we know how to determine both the delta and the amount of
borrowing, we can write the value of the call as:
We will find this intuition very useful in explaining the Black–Scholes
model.
RISK-NEUTRAL VALUATION Before leaving this simple example,
we should comment on a remarkable feature. We found the exact value of
the option without even knowing the probability that the stock would go
up or down! If an optimist thought the probability of an up move was very
high and a pessimist thought it was very low, they would still agree on the
option value. How could that be? The answer is that the current $50 stock
price already balances the views of the optimist and the pessimist. The
option reflects that balance because its value depends on the stock price.
This insight provides us with another approach to valuing the call. If
we don’t need the probabilities of the two states to value the call, perhaps
we can select any probabilities we want and still come up with the right
answer. Suppose we selected probabilities such that the return on the stock
is equal to the risk-free rate of 10 percent. We know that the stock return
given a rise is 20 percent (= $60/$50 − 1) and the stock return given a fall
is −20 percent (= $40/$50 − 1). Thus, we can solve for the probability of a
rise necessary to achieve an expected return of 10 percent as:
Solving this formula, we find that the probability of a rise is 3/4 and
the probability of a fall is 1/4. If we apply these probabilities to the call,
953
we can value it as:
the same value that we got from the duplicating approach.
Why did we select probabilities such that the expected return on the
stock is 10 percent? We wanted to work with the special case where
investors are risk-neutral. This case occurs when the expected return on
any asset (including both the stock and the call) is equal to the risk-free
rate. In other words, this case occurs when investors demand no additional
compensation beyond the risk-free rate, regardless of the risk of the asset
in question.
What would have happened if we had assumed that the expected return
on the stock was greater than the risk-free rate? The value of the call
would still be $6.82. However, the calculations would be more difficult.
For example, if we assumed that the expected return on the
page 531
stock was, say 11 percent, we would have had to derive the
expected return on the call. Although the expected return on the call would
be higher than 11 percent, it would take a lot of work to determine it
precisely. Why do any more work than you have to? Because we can’t
think of any good reason, we (and most other financial economists) choose
to assume risk-neutrality.
Thus, the preceding material allows us to value a call in the following
two ways:
1. Determine the cost of a strategy to duplicate the call. This strategy
involves an investment in a fractional share of stock financed by
partial borrowing.
2. Calculate the probabilities of a rise and a fall under the assumption of
risk-neutrality. Use those probabilities, in conjunction with the riskfree rate, to discount the payoffs of the call at expiration.
The Black–Scholes Model
The preceding example illustrates the duplicating strategy. Unfortunately,
a strategy such as this will not work in the real world over, say, a one-year
time frame, because there are many more than two possibilities for next
year’s stock price. However, the number of possibilities is reduced as the
time period is shortened. In fact, the assumption that there are only two
954
possibilities for the stock price over the next infinitesimal instant is quite
plausible.8
There’s a Black–Scholes calculator (and a lot more) at www.numa.com.
In our opinion, the fundamental insight of Black and Scholes is to
shorten the time period. They show that a specific combination of stock
and borrowing can indeed duplicate a call over an infinitesimal time
horizon. Because the price of the stock will change over the first instant,
another combination of stock and borrowing is needed to duplicate the call
over the second instant and so on. By adjusting the combination from
moment to moment, one can continually duplicate the call. It may boggle
the mind that a formula can (1) determine the duplicating combination at
any moment and (2) value the option based on this duplicating strategy.
Suffice it to say that their dynamic strategy allows one to value a call in
the real world, just as we showed how to value a call in the two-state
model.
This is the basic intuition behind the Black–Scholes model. Because
the actual derivation of their formula is, alas, far beyond the scope of this
text, we simply present the formula itself. The formula is:
where:
This formula for the value of a call, C, is one of the most complex in
finance. However, it involves only five parameters:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
S = Current stock price.
E = Exercise price of call.
R = Annual risk-free rate of return, continuously compounded.
σ2 = Variance (per year) of the continuous return on the stock.
t = Time (in years) to expiration date.
page 532
955
The small e in the formula is the mathematical constant 2.71828. . . . In
addition, there is the statistical concept:
Rather than discuss the formula in its algebraic state, we illustrate the
formula with an example:
EXAMPLE
17.4
Black–Scholes
Consider Private Equipment Company (PEC). On October 4 of Year 0,
the PEC April 49 call option has a closing value of $4. The stock itself is
selling at $50. The option has 199 days to expiration (maturity date =
April 21, Year 1). The annual risk-free interest rate, continuously
compounded, is 7 percent.
This information determines three variables directly:
1. The stock price, S, is $50.
2. The exercise price, E, is $49.
3. The risk-free rate, R, is .07.
In addition, the time to maturity, t, can be calculated quickly: The
formula calls for t to be expressed in years.
4. We express the 199-day interval in years as t = 199/365.
In the real world, an option trader would know S and E exactly.
Traders generally view U.S. Treasury bills as riskless, so a current
quote from The Wall Street Journal or a similar source would be
obtained for the interest rate. The trader would also know (or could
count) the number of days to expiration exactly. Thus, the fraction of a
year to expiration, t, could be calculated quickly.
The problem comes in determining the variance of the stock’s
return. The formula calls for the variance in effect between the purchase
date of October 4 and the expiration date. Unfortunately, this represents
the future, so the correct value for variance is simply not available.
Instead, traders frequently estimate variance from past data, just as we
calculated variance in an earlier chapter. In addition, some traders may
use intuition to adjust their estimate. For example, if anticipation of an
upcoming event is currently increasing the volatility of the stock, the
trader might adjust her estimate of variance upward to reflect this. (This
problem was most severe right after the October 19, 1987, crash. The
956
stock market was quite risky in the aftermath, so estimates using
precrash data were too low.)
The above discussion was intended merely to mention the
difficulties in variance estimation, not to present a solution. For our
purposes, we assume that a trader has come up with an estimate of
variance:
5. The variance of PEC has been estimated to be .09 per year.
Using the above five parameters, we calculate the Black–Scholes
value of the PEC option in three steps:
Step 1: Calculate d1 and d2. These values can be determined by a
straightforward, albeit tedious, insertion of our parameters into the basic
formula. We have
page 533
FIGURE 17.10
Graph of Cumulative Probability
Step 2: Calculate N(d1) and N(d2). The values N(d1) and N(d2) can
best be understood by examining Figure 17.10. The figure shows the
normal distribution with an expected value of 0 and a standard deviation
957
of 1. This is frequently called the standardized normal distribution.
We mentioned in an earlier chapter that the probability that a drawing
from this distribution will be between −1 and +1 (within one standard
deviation of its mean, in other words) is 68.26 percent.
Now let us ask a different question. What is the probability that a
drawing from the standardized normal distribution will be below a
particular value? For example, the probability that a drawing will be
below 0 is clearly 50 percent because the normal distribution is
symmetric. Using statistical terminology, we say that the cumulative
probability of 0 is 50 percent. Statisticians also say that N(0) = 50%. It
turns out that
The first value means that there is a 64.59 percent probability that a
drawing from the standardized normal distribution will be below .3742.
The second value means that there is a 56.07 percent probability that a
drawing from the standardized normal distribution will be below .1527.
More generally, N(d) is the notation that a drawing from the
standardized normal distribution will be below d. In other words, N(d) is
the cumulative probability of d. Note that d1 and d2 in our example are
slightly above zero, so N(d1) and N(d2) are slightly greater than .50.
Perhaps the easiest way to determine N(d1) and N(d2) is from the
Excel function NORMSDIST. In our example, NORMSDIST(.3742) and
NORMSDIST(.1527) are .6459 and .5607, respectively.
We can also determine the cumulative probability from Table 17.3.
For example, consider d = .37. This can be found in the table as .3 on
the vertical and .07 on the horizontal. The value in the table for d = .37
is .1443. This value is not the cumulative probability of .37. One must
first make an adjustment to determine cumulative probability. That is:
Unfortunately, our table handles only two significant digits, whereas
our value of .3742 has four significant digits. Hence, we must
interpolate to find N(.3742). Because N(.37) = .6443 and N(.38) =
.6480, the difference between the two values is .0037 (= .6480 − .6443).
Because .3742 is 42 percent of the way between .37 and .38, we
interpolate as:9
TABLE 17.3
Cumulative Probabilities of the Standard Normal Distribution
Function
958
d
.00
.01
.02
.03
.04
.05
.06
.07
.0
.0000
.0040
.0080
.0120
.0160
.0199
.0239
.0279
.1
.0398
.0438
.0478
.0517
.0557
.0596
.0636
.0675
.2
.0793
.0832
.0871
.0910
.0948
.0987
.1026
.1064
.3
.1179
.1217
.1255
.1293
.1331
.1368
.1406
.1443
.4
.1554
.1591
.1628
.1664
.1700
.1736
.1772
.1808
.5
.1915
.1950
.1985
.2019
.2054
.2088
.2123
.2157
.6
.2257
.2291
.2324
.2357
.2389
.2422
.2454
.2486
.7
.2580
.2611
.2642
.2673
.2704
.2734
.2764
.2794
.8
.2881
.2910
.2939
.2967
.2995
.3023
.3051
.3078
.9
.3159
.3186
.3212
.3238
.3264
.3289
.3315
.3340
1.0
.3413
.3438
.3461
.3485
.3508
.3531
.3554
.3577
1.1
.3643
.3665
.3686
.3708
.3729
.3749
.3770
.3790
1.2
.3849
.3869
.3888
.3907
.3925
.3944
.3962
.3980
1.3
.4032
.4049
.4066
.4082
.4099
.4115
.4131
.4147
1.4
.4192
.4207
.4222
.4236
.4251
.4265
.4279
.4292
1.5
.4332
.4345
.4357
.4370
.4382
.4394
.4406
.4418
1.6
.4452
.4463
.4474
.4484
.4495
.4505
.4515
.4525
1.7
.4554
.4564
.4573
.4582
.4591
.4599
.4608
.4616
1.8
.4641
.4649
.4656
.4664
.4671
.4678
.4686
.4693
1.9
.4713
.4719
.4726
.4732
.4738
.4744
.4750
.4756
2.0
.4773
.4778
.4783
.4788
.4793
.4798
.4803
.4808
2.1
.4821
.4826
.4830
.4834
.4838
.4842
.4846
.4850
2.2
.4861
.4866
.4830
.4871
.4875
.4878
.4881
.4884
2.3
.4893
.4896
.4898
.4901
.4904
.4906
.4909
.4911
2.4
.4918
.4920
.4922
.4925
.4927
.4929
.4931
.4932
2.5
.4938
.4940
.4941
.4943
.4945
.4946
.4948
.4949
2.6
.4953
.4955
.4956
.4957
.4959
.4960
.4961
.4962
2.7
.4965
.4966
.4967
.4968
.4969
.4970
.4971
.4972
2.8
.4974
.4975
.4976
.4977
.4977
.4978
.4979
.4979
959
2.9
.4981
.4982
.4982
.4982
.4984
.4984
.4985
.4985
3.0
.4987
.4987
.4987
.4988
.4988
.4989
.4989
.4989
N(d) represents areas under the standard normal distribution function. Suppose that d1 = .24.
This table implies a cumulative probability of .5000 + .0948 = .5948. If d1 is equal to .2452, we
must estimate the probability by interpolating between N(.25) and N(.24).
page 534
Step 3: Calculate C. We have:
The estimated price of $5.85 is greater than the $4 actual price,
implying that the call option is underpriced. A trader believing in the
Black–Scholes model would buy a call. Of course, the Black–Scholes
model is fallible. Perhaps the disparity between the model’s estimate
and the market price reflects error in the trader’s estimate of variance.
page 535
The previous example stressed the calculations involved in using the
Black–Scholes formula. Is there any intuition behind the formula? Yes,
and that intuition follows from the stock purchase and borrowing strategy
in our binomial example. The Black–Scholes equation is:
which is exactly analogous to Equation 17.2:
that we presented in the binomial example. It turns out that N(d1) is the
delta in the Black–Scholes formula. N(d1) is .6459 in the previous
example. In addition, Ee−Rt N(d2) is the amount that an investor must
borrow to duplicate a call. In the previous example, this value is $26.45 (=
$49 × .9626 × .5607). Thus, the model tells us that we can duplicate the
960
call of the preceding example by both:
Another good options calculator can be found at
www.margrabe.com/optionpricing.html.
1. Buying .6459 share of stock.
2. Borrowing $26.45.
It is no exaggeration to say that the Black–Scholes formula is among
the most important contributions in finance. It allows anyone to calculate
the value of an option given a few parameters. The attraction of the
formula is that four of the parameters are observable: the current price of
stock, S, the exercise price, E, the interest rate, R, and the time to
expiration date, t. Only one of the parameters must be estimated: the
variance of return, σ2.
To see how truly attractive this formula is, note what parameters are
not needed. First, the investor’s risk aversion does not affect the option
value. The formula can be used by anyone, regardless of willingness to
bear risk. Second, it does not depend on the expected return on the stock!
Investors with different assessments of the stock’s expected return will
nevertheless agree on the call price. As in the two-state example, this is
because the call depends on the stock price and that price already balances
investors’ divergent views.
17.9 STOCKS AND BONDS AS OPTIONS
The previous material in this chapter described, explained, and valued
publicly traded options. This is important material to any finance student
because much trading occurs in these listed options. The study of options
has another purpose for the student of corporate finance.
You may have heard the one-liner about the elderly gentleman who
was surprised to learn that he had been speaking prose all of his life. The
same can be said about the corporate finance student and options.
Although options were formally defined for the first time in this chapter,
we can actually describe the corporation in terms of options.
We begin by illustrating the implicit options in stocks and bonds
through a simple example.
961
EXAMPLE
17.5
Stocks and Bonds as Options
The Popov Company has been awarded the concessions at next year’s
Olympic Games in Antarctica. Because the firm’s principals do not live
in Antarctica and because there is no other concession business in that
continent, their enterprise will disband after the games. The firm has
issued debt to help finance this venture. Interest and principal due on
the debt next year will be $800, at which time the debt will be paid off in
full. The firm’s cash flows next year are forecasted as
page 536
POPOV’S CASH FLOW SCHEDULE
VERY
SUCCESSFUL
GAMES
MODERATELY
SUCCESSFUL
GAMES
MODERATELY
UNSUCCESSFUL
GAMES
$1,000
$850
$700
800
− 800
$ 200
$ 50
Cash flow before
interest and principal
− Interest and principal
Cash flow to stockholders
−
−
$
As can be seen, the principals forecasted four equally likely scenarios.
If either of the first two scenarios occurs, the bondholders will be paid in
full. The extra cash flow goes to the stockholders. However, if either of
the last two scenarios occurs, the bondholders will not be paid in full.
Instead, they will receive the firm’s entire cash flow, leaving the
stockholders with nothing.
This example is similar to the bankruptcy examples presented in our
chapters on capital structure. Our new insight is that the relationship
between the common stock and the firm can be expressed in terms of
options. We consider call options first because the intuition is easier. The
put option scenario is treated next.
The Firm Expressed in Terms of Call Options
962
THE STOCKHOLDERS We now show that stock can be viewed as a
call option on the firm. To illustrate this, Figure 17.11 graphs the cash flow
to the stockholders as a function of the cash flow to the firm. The
stockholders receive nothing if the firm’s cash flows are less than $800;
here, all of the cash flows go to the bondholders. However, the
stockholders earn a dollar for every dollar that the firm receives above
$800. The graph looks exactly like the call option graphs that we
considered earlier in this chapter.
But what is the underlying asset upon which the stock is a call option?
The underlying asset is the firm itself. That is, we can view the
bondholders as owning the firm. However, the stockholders have a call
option on the firm with an exercise price of $800.
FIGURE 17.11
Cash Flow to Stockholders of Popov Company as a Function of Cash
Flow to Firm
If the firm’s cash flow is above $800, the stockholders would choose to
exercise this option. In other words, they would buy the firm from the
bondholders for $800. Their net cash flow is the difference
page 537
between the firm’s cash flow and their $800 payment. This
would be $200 (= $1,000 − 800) if the games are very successful and $50
(= $850 − 800) if the games are moderately successful.
FIGURE 17.12
Cash Flow to Bondholders of Popov Company as a Function of Cash
Flow to Firm
963
Should the value of the firm’s cash flows be less than $800, the
stockholders would not choose to exercise their option. Instead, they
would walk away from the firm, as any call option holder would do. The
bondholders then would receive the firm’s entire cash flow.
This view of the firm is a novel one, and students are frequently
bothered by it on first exposure. However, we encourage students to keep
looking at the firm in this way until the view becomes second nature to
them.
THE BONDHOLDERS What about the bondholders? Our earlier cash
flow schedule showed that they would get the entire cash flow of the firm
if the firm generated less cash than $800. Should the firm earn more than
$800, the bondholders would receive only $800. That is, they would be
entitled only to interest and principal. This schedule is graphed in Figure
17.12.
In keeping with our view that the stockholders have a call option on
the firm, what does the bondholders’ position consist of? The bondholders’
position can be described by two claims:
1. They own the firm.
2. They have written a call against the firm with an exercise price of
$800.
As we mentioned before, the stockholders walk away from the firm if
cash flows are less than $800. Thus, the bondholders retain ownership in
this case. However, if the cash flows are greater than $800, the
stockholders exercise their option. They call the stock away from the
964
bondholders for $800.
The Firm Expressed in Terms of Put Options
The preceding analysis expresses the positions of the stockholders and the
bondholders in terms of call options. We can now express the situation in
terms of put options.
THE STOCKHOLDERS The stockholders’ position can be expressed
by three claims:
1. They own the firm.
2. They owe $800 in interest and principal to the bondholders.
If the debt were risk-free, these two claims would fully
describe the stockholders’ situation. However, because of the
possibility of default, we have a third claim as well:
page 538
3. The stockholders own a put option on the firm with an exercise price
of $800. The group of bondholders is the seller of the put.
Now consider two possibilities:
CASH FLOW IS LESS THAN $800 Because the put has an exercise
price of $800, the put is in the money. The stockholders “put,” that is, sell,
the firm to the bondholders. Normally, the holder of a put receives the
exercise price when the asset is sold. However, the stockholders already
owe $800 to the bondholders. Thus, the debt of $800 is simply canceled—
and no money changes hands—when the stock is delivered to the
bondholders. Because the stockholders give up the stock in exchange for
extinguishing the debt, the stockholders end up with nothing if the cash
flow is below $800.
CASH FLOW IS GREATER THAN $800 Because the put is out of
the money here, the stockholders do not exercise. Thus, the stockholders
retain ownership of the firm but pay $800 to the bondholders as interest
and principal.
THE BONDHOLDERS The bondholders’ position can be described by
two claims:
965
1. The bondholders are owed $800.
2. They have sold a put option on the firm to the stockholders with an
exercise price of $800.
CASH FLOW IS LESS THAN $800 As mentioned before, the
stockholders will exercise the put in this case. This means that the
bondholders are obligated to pay $800 for the firm. Because they are owed
$800, the two obligations offset each other. Thus, the bondholders simply
end up with the firm in this case.
CASH FLOW IS GREATER THAN $800 Here, the stockholders do
not exercise the put. Thus, the bondholders merely receive the $800 that is
due them.
Expressing the bondholders’ position in this way is illuminating. With
a riskless default-free bond, the bondholders are owed $800. Thus, we can
express the risky bond in terms of a riskless bond and a put:
That is, the value of the risky bond is the value of the default-free bond
less the value of the stockholders’ option to sell the company for $800.
A Resolution of the Two Views
We have argued above that the positions of the stockholders and the
bondholders can be viewed either in terms of calls or in terms of puts.
These two viewpoints are summarized in Table 17.4:
We have found from past experience that it is generally harder for
students to think of the firm in terms of puts than in terms of calls. Thus, it
would be helpful if there were a way to show that the two viewpoints are
equivalent. Fortunately, there is put–call parity. In an earlier section, we
presented the put–call parity relationship as Equation 17.1, which we now
repeat:
page 539
TABLE 17.4
Positions of Stockholders and Bondholders in Popov Company in Terms of Calls and
966
Puts
STOCKHOLDERS
BONDHOLDERS
Positions Viewed in Terms of Call
Options
1. Stockholders own a call on the
firm with exercise price of $800.
1. Bondholders own the firm.
2. Bondholders have sold a call
on the firm to the
stockholders.
Positions Viewed in Terms of Put
Options
1. Stockholders own the firm.
2. Stockholders owe $800 in interest
and principal to bondholders.
3. Stockholders own a put option on
the firm with exercise price of
$800.
1. Bondholders are owed $800
in interest and principal.
2. Bondholders have sold a put
on the firm to the
stockholders.
Using the results of this section, Equation 17.1 can be rewritten as:
Going from Equation 17.1 to Equation 17.4 involves a few steps. First, we
treat the firm, not the stock, as the underlying asset in this section. (In
keeping with common convention, we refer to the value of the firm and the
price of the stock.) Second, the exercise price is now $800, the principal
and interest on the firm’s debt. Taking the present value of this amount at
the riskless rate yields the value of a default-free bond. Third, the order of
the terms in Equation 17.1 is rearranged in Equation 17.4.
Note that the left-hand side of Equation 17.4 is the stockholders’
position in terms of call options, as shown in Table 17.4. The right-hand
side of Equation 17.4 is the stockholders’ position in terms of put options,
as shown in the table. Thus, put–call parity shows that viewing the
stockholders’ position in terms of call options is equivalent to viewing the
stockholders’ position in terms of put options.
Now, let’s rearrange the terms in Equation 17.4 to yield:
967
The left-hand side of Equation 17.5 is the bondholders’ position in
terms of call options, as shown in Table 17.4. The right-hand side of the
equation is the bondholders’ position in terms of put options, as shown in
Table 17.4. Thus, put–call parity shows that viewing the bondholders’
position in terms of call options is equivalent to viewing the bondholders’
position in terms of put options.
A Note on Loan Guarantees
In the Popov example given earlier, the bondholders bore the risk of
default. Of course, bondholders generally ask for an interest rate that is
enough to compensate them for bearing risk. When firms experience
financial distress, they can no longer attract new debt at moderate interest
rates. Thus, firms experiencing distress have frequently sought loan
guarantees from the government. Our framework can be used to
understand these guarantees.
page 540
If the firm defaults on a guaranteed loan, the government must make
up the difference. In other words, a government guarantee converts a risky
bond into a riskless bond. What is the value of this guarantee?
Recall that, with option pricing:
This equation shows that the government is assuming an obligation that
has a cost equal to the value of a put option.
This analysis differs from that of either politicians or company
spokespeople. They generally say that the guarantee will cost the taxpayer
nothing because the guarantee enables the firm to attract debt, thereby
staying solvent. However, it should be pointed out that, although solvency
may be a strong possibility, it is never a certainty. Thus, at the time when
the guarantee is made, the government’s obligation has a cost in terms of
present value. To say that a government guarantee costs the government
nothing is like saying a put on the stock of Microsoft has no value because
the stock is likely to rise in price.
968
Who benefits from a typical loan guarantee?
1. If existing risky bonds are guaranteed, all gains accrue to the existing
bondholders. The stockholders gain nothing because the limited
liability of corporations absolves the stockholders of any obligation in
bankruptcy.
2. If new debt is being issued and guaranteed, the new debtholders do
not gain. Rather, in a competitive market, they must accept a low
interest rate because of the debt’s low risk. The stockholders gain
here because they are able to issue debt at a low interest rate. In
addition, some of the gains accrue to the old bondholders because the
firm’s value is greater than would otherwise be true. Therefore, if
shareholders want all the gains from loan guarantees, they should
renegotiate or retire existing bonds before the guarantee is in place.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
This chapter serves as an introduction to options.
1.
The most familiar options are puts and calls. These options
give the holder the right to sell or buy shares of common stock
at a given exercise price. American options can be exercised
any time up to and including the expiration date. European
options can be exercised only on the expiration date.
2.
We showed that a strategy of buying a stock and buying a put
is equivalent to a strategy of buying a call and buying a zero
coupon bond. From this, the put–call parity relationship was
established:
3.
The value of an option depends on five factors:
a.
b.
c.
d.
e.
The price of the underlying asset.
The exercise price.
The expiration date.
The variability of the underlying asset’s return.
The interest rate on risk-free bonds.
The Black–Scholes model can determine the intrinsic price of
an option from these five factors.
4.
The positions of stockholders and bondholders can be
969
described in terms of calls and puts.
page 541
CONCEPT QUESTIONS
1.
Options What is a call option? A put option? Under what
circumstances might you want to buy each? Which one has greater
potential profit? Why?
2.
Options Complete the following sentence for each of these
investors:
a.
b.
c.
d.
A buyer of call options
A buyer of put options
A seller (writer) of call options
A seller (writer) of put options
“The (buyer/seller) of a (put/call) option (pays/receives) money for the
(right/obligation) to (buy/ sell) a specified asset at a fixed price for a fixed
length of time.”
3.
American and European Options What is the difference between
an American option and a European option?
4.
Intrinsic Value What is the intrinsic value of a call option? Of a put
option? How do we interpret this value?
5.
Option Pricing You notice that shares of stock in the Patel
Corporation are going for $50 per share. Call options with an exercise
price of $35 per share are selling for $10. What’s wrong here?
Describe how you can take advantage of this mispricing if the option
expires today.
6.
Options and Stock Risk If the risk of a stock increases, what is
likely to happen to the price of call options on the stock? To the price
of put options? Why?
7.
Option Rise True or false: The unsystematic risk of a share of stock
is irrelevant in valuing the stock because it can be diversified away;
therefore, it is also irrelevant for valuing a call option on the stock.
Explain.
8.
Option Pricing Suppose a certain stock currently sells for $30 per
share. If a put option and a call option are available with $30 exercise
prices, which do you think will sell for more, the put or the call?
970
Explain.
9.
Option Price and Interest Rates Suppose the interest rate on Tbills suddenly and unexpectedly rises. All other things being the same,
what is the impact on call option values? On put option values?
10.
Contingent Liabilities When you take out an ordinary student loan,
it is often the case that whoever holds that loan is given a guarantee
by the U.S. government, meaning that the government will make up
any payments you skip. This is just one example of the many loan
guarantees made by the U.S. government. Such guarantees don’t
show up in calculations of government spending or in official deficit
figures. Why not? Should they show up?
11.
Options and Expiration Dates What is the impact of lengthening
the time to expiration on an option’s value? Explain.
12.
Options and Stock Price Volatility What is the impact of an
increase in the volatility of the underlying stock’s return on an option’s
value? Explain.
13.
Insurance as an Option An insurance policy is considered
analogous to an option. From the policyholder’s point of view, what
type of option is an insurance policy? Why?
14.
Equity as a Call Option It is said that the equityholders of a levered
firm can be thought of as holding a call option on the firm’s assets.
Explain what is meant by this statement.
15.
Option Valuation and NPV You are CEO of Titan Industries and
have just been awarded a large number of employee stock options.
The company has two mutually exclusive projects available. The first
project has a large NPV and will reduce the total risk of the company.
The second project has a small NPV and will increase the total risk of
the company. You have decided to accept the first project when you
remember your employee stock options. How might this affect your
decision?
16.
Put–Call Parity You find a put and a call with the same exercise
price and maturity. What do you know about the relative prices of the
put and call? Prove your answer and provide an intuitive explanation.
17.
Put–Call Parity A put and a call have the same maturity page 542
and strike price. If they have the same price, which one is
in the money? Prove your answer and provide an intuitive explanation.
18.
Put–Call Parity One thing put-call parity tells us is that given any
three of a stock, a call, a put, and a T-bill, the fourth can be
synthesized or replicated using the other three. For example, how can
971
we replicate a share of stock using a call, a put, and a T-bill?
QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS
Basic (Questions 1–14)
1.
Understanding Option Quotes Use the option quote
information shown here to answer the questions that follow.
The stock is currently selling for $82.
OPTION
AND NY
CLOSE
CALLS
EXPIRATION
STRIKE
PRICE
VOL.
Mar
80
230
Apr
80
Jul
Oct
PUTS
LAST
VOL.
LAST
1.90
160
.80
170
6
127
1.40
80
139
8.05
43
3.90
80
60
10.20
11
3.65
RWJ
a. Are the call options in the money? What is the intrinsic value
of an RWJ Corp. call option?
b. Are the put options in the money? What is the intrinsic value
of an RWJ Corp. put option?
c. Two of the options are clearly mispriced. Which ones? At a
minimum, what should the mispriced options sell for?
Explain how you could profit from the mispricing in each
case.
2.
Calculating Payoffs Use the option quote information shown
below to answer the questions that follow. The stock is
currently selling for $97.
OPTION
AND NY
CLOSE
CALLS
PUTS
EXPIRATION
STRIKE
PRICE
VOL.
LAST
VOL.
LAST
Feb
95
85
2.85
40
1.13
Macrosoft
972
Mar
95
61
5.25
22
4.05
May
95
22
7.78
11
5.94
Aug
95
3
10.20
3
9.12
a. Suppose you buy 10 contracts of the February 95 call
option. How much will you pay, ignoring commissions?
b. In part (a), suppose that Macrosoft stock is selling for $105
per share on the expiration date. How much is your options
investment worth? What if the terminal stock price is $112?
Explain.
c. Suppose you buy 10 contracts of the August 95 put option.
What is your maximum gain? On the expiration date,
Macrosoft is selling for $89 per share. How much is your
options investment worth? What is your net gain?
d. In part (c), suppose you sell 10 of the August 95 put
contracts. What is your net gain or loss if Macrosoft is
selling for $87 at expiration? For $103? What is the breakeven price, that is, the terminal stock price that results in a
zero profit?
Put–Call
3.
Parity A stock is currently selling for $47 per share. A
call option with an exercise price of $50 sells for $2.61 and
expires in three months. If the risk-free rate of interest is 3.9
percent per year, compounded continuously, what is the price
of a put option with the same exercise price?
4.
Put–Call Parity A put option that expires in five
page 543
months with an exercise price of $60 sells for $2.87.
The stock is currently priced at $58, and the risk-free rate is 4.1
percent per year, compounded continuously. What is the price
of a call option with the same exercise price?
5.
Put–Call Parity A put option and a call option with an
exercise price of $60 and three months to expiration sell for
$3.87 and $4.89, respectively. If the risk-free rate is 2.7 percent
per year, compounded continuously, what is the current stock
price?
6.
Put–Call Parity A put option and a call option with an
exercise price of $90 expire in four months and sell for $7.05
and $11.74, respectively. If the stock is currently priced at
$94.13, what is the annual continuously compounded rate of
interest?
973
7.
Black–Scholes What are the prices of a call option and a put
option with the following characteristics?
8.
Black–Scholes What are the prices of a call option and a put
option with the following characteristics?
Delta
9.
What are the deltas of a call option and a put option with the
following characteristics? What does the delta of the option tell
you?
10.
Black–Scholes and Asset Value You own a lot in Key West,
Florida, that is currently unused. Similar lots have recently sold
for $1.45 million. Over the past five years, the price of land in
the area has increased 7 percent per year, with an annual
standard deviation of 25 percent. A buyer has recently
approached you and wants an option to buy the land in the next
12 months for $1.6 million. The risk-free rate of interest is 5
percent per year, compounded continuously. How much should
you charge for the option?
11.
Black–Scholes and Asset Value In the previous problem,
suppose you wanted the option to sell the land to the buyer in
one year. Assuming all the facts are the same, describe the
transaction that would occur today. What is the price of the
transaction today?
974
12.
Time Value of Options You are given the following
information concerning options on a particular stock:
a. What is the intrinsic value of the call option? Of
page 544
the put option?
b. What is the time value of the call option? Of the put option?
c. Does the call or the put have the larger time value
component? Would you expect this to be true in general?
13.
Risk-Neutral Valuation A stock is currently priced at $58.
The stock will either increase or decrease by 13 percent over
the next year. There is a call option on the stock with a strike
price of $55 and one year until expiration. If the risk-free rate is
6 percent, what is the risk-neutral value of the call option?
14.
Risk-Neutral Valuation In the previous problem, assume the
risk-free rate is only 4 percent. What is the risk-neutral value of
the option now? What happens to the risk-neutral probabilities
of a stock price increase and a stock price decrease?
Intermediate (Questions 15–25)
15.
Black–Scholes A call option matures in six months. The
underlying stock price is $75, and the stock’s return has a
standard deviation of 20 percent per year. The risk-free rate is
4 percent per year, compounded continuously. If the exercise
price is $0, what is the price of the call option?
16.
Black–Scholes A call option has an exercise price of $65
and matures in six months. The current stock price is $68, and
the risk-free rate is 4 percent per year, compounded
continuously. What is the price of the call if the standard
deviation of the stock is 0 percent per year?
17.
Black–Scholes A stock is currently priced at $35. A call
option with an expiration of one year has an exercise price of
$40. The risk-free rate is 3 percent per year, compounded
continuously, and the standard deviation of the stock’s return is
infinitely large. What is the price of the call option?
18.
Equity as an Option Sunburn Sunscreen has a zero coupon
975
bond issue outstanding with a $15,000 face value that matures
in one year. The current market value of the firm’s assets is
$16,100. The standard deviation of the return on the firm’s
assets is 32 percent per year, and the annual risk-free rate is 6
percent per year, compounded continuously. Based on the
Black–Scholes model, what is the market value of the firm’s
equity and debt?
19.
Equity as an Option and NPV Suppose the firm in the
previous problem is considering two mutually exclusive
investments. Project A has an NPV of $800, and Project B has
an NPV of $1,300. As a result of taking Project A, the standard
deviation of the return on the firm’s assets will increase to 50
percent per year. If Project B is taken, the standard deviation
will fall to 23 percent per year.
a. What is the value of the firm’s equity and debt if Project A is
undertaken? If Project B is undertaken?
b. Which project would the stockholders prefer? Can you
reconcile your answer with the NPV rule?
c. Suppose the stockholders and bondholders are in fact the
same group of investors. Would this affect your answer to
(b)?
d. What does this problem suggest to you about stockholder
incentives?
20.
Equity as an Option Frostbite Thermalwear has a zero coupon
bond issue outstanding with a face value of $22,000 that
matures in one year. The current market value of the firm’s
assets is $23,200. The standard deviation of the return on the
firm’s assets is 34 percent per year, and the annual risk-free
rate is 6 percent per year, compounded continuously. Based on
the Black–Scholes model, what is the market value of the firm’s
equity and debt? What is the firm’s continuously compounded
cost of debt?
21.
Equity as an Option and NPV A company has a single zero
coupon bond outstanding that matures in 10 years and has a
face value of $12 million. The current value of the company’s
assets is $10.7 million, and the standard deviation of the return
on the firm’s assets is 47 percent per year. The risk-free rate is
6 percent per year, compounded continuously.
a. What is the current market value of the company’s equity?
b. What is the current market value of the company’s debt?
976
c. What is the company’s continuously compounded cost of
debt?
d. The company has a new project available. The project has an
NPV of $1.3 million. If the company undertakes the project,
what will be the new market value of equity? Assume volatility
is unchanged.
e. Assuming the company undertakes the new
page 545
project and does not borrow any additional funds,
what is the new continuously compounded cost of debt? What
is happening here?
22.
Two-State Option Pricing Model Ken is interested in buying
a European call option written on Southeastern Airlines, Inc., a
non-dividend-paying common stock, with a strike price of $60
and one year until expiration. Currently, the company’s stock
sells for $64 per share. In one year, Ken knows that the stock
will be trading at either $71 per share or $56 per share. Ken is
able to borrow and lend at the risk-free EAR of 5.5 percent.
a. What should the call option sell for today?
b. If no options currently trade on the stock, is there a way to
create a synthetic call option with identical payoffs to the call
option described above? If there is, how would you do it?
c. How much does the synthetic call option cost? Is this greater
than, less than, or equal to what the actual call option costs?
Does this make sense?
23.
Two-State Option Pricing Model Rob wishes to buy a
European put option on BioLabs, Inc., a non-dividend-paying
common stock, with a strike price of $75 and six months until
expiration. The company’s common stock is currently selling for
$73 per share, and Rob expects that the stock price will either
rise to $83 or fall to $61 in six months. Rob can borrow and
lend at the risk-free EAR of 4.3 percent.
a. What should the put option sell for today?
b. If no options currently trade on the stock, is there a way to
create a synthetic put option with identical payoffs to the put
option described above? If there is, how would you do it?
c. How much does the synthetic put option cost? Is this greater
than, less than, or equal to what the actual put option costs?
Does this make sense?
24.
Two-State Option Pricing Model Maverick Manufacturing,
977
Inc., must purchase gold in three months for use in its
operations. Maverick’s management has estimated that if the
price of gold were to rise above $1,310 per ounce, the firm
would go bankrupt. The current price of gold is $1,230 per
ounce. The firm’s chief financial officer believes that the price of
gold will either rise to $1,350 per ounce or fall to $1,120 per
ounce over the next three months. Management wishes to
eliminate any risk of the firm going bankrupt. The company can
borrow and lend at the risk-free EAR of 4 percent.
a. Should the company buy a call option or a put option on gold?
In order to avoid bankruptcy, what strike price and time to
expiration would the company like this option to have?
b. How much should such an option sell for in the open market?
c. If no options currently trade on gold, is there a way for the
company to create a synthetic option with identical payoffs to
the option described above? If there is, how would the firm do
it?
d. How much does the synthetic option cost? Is this greater
than, less than, or equal to what the actual option costs?
Does this make sense?
25.
Black–Scholes and Collar Cost An investor is said to take a
position in a “collar” if she buys the asset, buys an out-of-themoney put option on the asset, and sells an out-of-the-money
call option on the asset. The two options should have the same
time to expiration. Suppose Marie wishes to purchase a collar
on Hollywood, Inc., a non-dividend-paying common stock, with
six months until expiration. She would like the put to have a
strike price of $50 and the call to have a strike price of $60. The
current price of the stock is $54 per share. Marie can borrow
and lend at the continuously compounded risk-free rate of 4.7
percent per year, and the annual standard deviation of the
stock’s return is 45 percent. Use the Black–Scholes model to
calculate the total cost of the collar that Marie is interested in
buying. What is the effect of the collar?
Challenge (Questions 26–35)
26.
Mergers and Equity as an Option Suppose Sunburn
Sunscreen (Problem 18) and Frostbite Thermalwear (Problem
20) have decided to merge. Since the two companies have
seasonal sales, the combined firm’s return on assets will have
a standard deviation of 16 percent per year.
978
a. What is the combined value of equity in the two existing
companies? Value of debt?
b. What is the value of the new firm’s equity? Value of debt?
c. What was the gain or loss for shareholders? For
page 546
bondholders?
d. What happened to shareholder value here?
27.
Debt Valuation and Time to Maturity Eagle Industries has a
zero coupon bond issue that matures in two years with a face
value of $75,000. The current value of the company’s assets is
$58,000, and the standard deviation of the return on assets is
60 percent per year.
a. Assume the risk-free rate is 5 percent per year, compounded
continuously. What is the value of a risk-free bond with the
same face value and maturity as the company’s bond?
b. What price would the bondholders have to pay for a put
option on the firm’s assets with a strike price equal to the face
value of the debt?
c. Using the answers from (a) and (b), what is the value of the
firm’s debt? What is the continuously compounded yield on
the company’s debt?
d. From an examination of the value of the assets of the
company, and the fact that the debt must be repaid in two
years, it seems likely that the company will default on its debt.
Management has approached bondholders and proposed a
plan whereby the company would repay the same face value
of debt, but the repayment would not occur for five years.
What is the value of the debt under the proposed plan? What
is the new continuously compounded yield on the debt?
Explain why this occurs.
28.
Debt Valuation and Asset Variance Watson Corp. has a
zero coupon bond that matures in five years with a face value
of $75,000. The current value of the company’s assets is
$61,000, and the standard deviation of its return on assets is
50 percent per year. The risk-free rate is 6 percent per year,
compounded continuously.
a. What is the value of a risk-free bond with the same face value
and maturity as the current bond?
b. What is the value of a put option on the firm’s assets with a
strike price equal to the face value of the debt?
979
c. Using the answers from (a) and (b), what is the value of the
firm’s debt? What is the continuously compounded yield on
the company’s debt?
d. Assume the company can restructure its assets so that the
standard deviation of its return on assets increases to 60
percent per year. What happens to the value of the debt?
What is the new continuously compounded yield on the debt?
Reconcile your answers in (c) and (d).
e. What happens to bondholders if the company restructures its
assets? What happens to shareholders? How does this
create an agency problem?
29.
Two-State Option Pricing and Corporate Valuation
Masters Real Estate, Inc., a construction firm financed by both
debt and equity, is undertaking a new project. If the project is
successful, the value of the firm in one year will be $125
million, but if the project is a failure, the firm will only be worth
$85 million. The company’s current value is $103 million, a
figure that includes the prospects for the new project. The
company has outstanding zero coupon bonds due in one year
with a face value of $95 million. Treasury bills that mature in
one year yield 7 percent EAR. The company pays no
dividends.
a. Use the two-state option pricing model to find the current
value of the company’s debt and equity.
b. Suppose the company has 300,000 shares of common stock
outstanding. What is the price per share of the firm’s equity?
c. Compare the market value of the company’s debt to the
present value of an equal amount of debt that is riskless with
one year until maturity. Is the firm’s debt worth more than,
less than, or the same as the riskless debt? Does this make
sense? What factors might cause these two values to be
different?
d. Suppose that in place of the project described above, the
company’s management decides to undertake a project that
is even more risky. The value of the firm will either increase to
$135 million or decrease to $70 million by the end of the year.
Use the two-state option pricing model to determine the value
of the firm’s debt and equity if the firm plans on undertaking
this new project. What is the stock price if the firm undertakes
this project? Which project do bondholders prefer?
30.
Black–Scholes and Dividends In addition to the
980
page 547
five factors discussed in the chapter, dividends also affect the
price of an option. The Black–Scholes option pricing model with
dividends is
All of the variables are the same as the Black–Scholes model
without dividends except for the variable d, which is the
continuously compounded dividend yield on the stock.
a. What effect do you think the dividend yield will have on the
price of a call option? Explain.
b. A stock is currently priced at $87 per share, the standard
deviation of its return is 50 percent per year, and the risk-free
rate is 5 percent per year, compounded continuously. What is
the price of a call option with a strike price of $80 and a
maturity of 4 months if the stock has a dividend yield of 2
percent per year?
31.
Put–Call Parity and Dividends The put–call parity condition
is altered when dividends are paid. The dividend adjusted put–
call parity formula is
where d is again the continuously compounded dividend yield.
a. What effect do you think the dividend yield will have on the
price of a put option? Explain.
b. From the previous question, what is the price of a put option
with the same strike price and time to expiration as the call
option?
32.
Put Delta The delta for a put option is N(d1) − 1. Is this the
same thing as −N(−d1)? (Hint: Yes, but why?)
33.
Black–Scholes Put Pricing Model Use the Black–Scholes
model for pricing a call, put–call parity, and the previous
question to show that the Black–Scholes model for directly
pricing a put can be written as
34.
Black–Scholes A stock is currently priced at $50. The stock
will never pay a dividend. The risk-free rate is 12 percent per
year, compounded continuously, and the standard deviation of
981
the stock’s return is 60 percent. A European call option on the
stock has a strike price of $100 and no expiration date,
meaning that it has an infinite life. Based on Black–Scholes,
what is the value of the call option? Do you see a paradox
here? Do you see a way out of the paradox?
35.
Delta You purchase one call and sell one put with the same
strike price and expiration date. What is the delta of your
portfolio? Why?
page 548
WHAT’S ON THE WEB?
1.
Black-Scholes Go to www.option-price.com. Find the stock option
calculator. The call option and put option on a stock expire in 30 days.
The strike price is $50 and the current stock price is $51.20. The
standard deviation of the stock is 60 percent per year, and the riskfree rate is 4.8 percent per year, compounded continuously. What are
the prices of the call and the put? What are the deltas?
2.
Black-Scholes Go to www.cboe.com, and find the options
calculator. A stock is currently priced at $93 per share, and its return
has a standard deviation of 48 percent per year. Options are available
with an exercise price of $90, and the risk-free rate is 5.2 percent per
year, compounded continuously. What are the prices of the call and
the put that expire next month? What are the deltas? How do your
answers change for an exercise price of $95?
3.
Black-Scholes with Dividends Recalculate the first two problems
assuming a dividend yield of 2 percent per year. How does this
change your answers? Can you explain why dividends have the effect
they do?
EXCEL MASTER IT! PROBLEM
In addition to spinners and scroll bars, there are numerous other
controls in Excel. For this assignment, you need to build a Black–
Scholes option pricing model spreadsheet using several of these
controls.
a.
Buttons are always used in sets. Using buttons permits you to
check an option, and the spreadsheet will use that input. In this
case, you need to create two buttons, one for a call option and
982
one for a put option. When using the spreadsheet, if you click the
call option, the spreadsheet will calculate a call price, and if you
click the put option, it will calculate the price of a put. Notice on the
next spreadsheet that cell B20 is empty. This cell should change
names. The names should be “Call option price” and “Put option
price.” In the price cell, only the price for the call option or put
option is displayed depending on which button is selected. For the
button, use the button under Form Controls.
b.
A combo box uses a drop-down menu with values entered by the
spreadsheet developer. One advantage of a combo box is that the
user can either choose values from the drop-down menu or enter
another value. In this case, you want to create one combo box for
the stock price and a separate combo box for the strike price. On
the right-hand side of the spreadsheet, we have values for the
dropdown menu. These values should be created in an array
before the combo box is inserted. To create an ActiveX combo
box, go to Developer, Insert, and select Combo Box from the
ActiveX Controls menu. After you draw the combo box, right-click
on the box, select Properties, and enter the LinkedCell, which is
the cell where you want the output displayed, and the
ListFillRange, which is the range that contains the list of values
you want displayed in the drop-down menu.
c.
In contrast to a combo box, a list box permits the user to scroll
through a list of possible values that are predetermined by the
spreadsheet developer. No other values can be entered. You
need to create a list box for the interest rate using the interest rate
array on the right-hand side of the spreadsheet. To insert a list
box, go to Developer, Insert, and choose the List Box from the
ActiveX Controls. To enter the linked cell and array of values,
right-click on List Box and select Properties from the menu. We
should note here that to edit both the combo box and list box you
will need to make sure that Design Mode is checked on the
Developer tab.
CLOSING CASE
EXOTIC CUISINES EMPLOYEE STOCK
OPTIONS
983
As a newly minted MBA, you’ve taken a management position with Exotic
Cuisines, Inc., a restaurant chain that just went public last year. The
company’s restaurants specialize in exotic main dishes, using ingredients
such as alligator, buffalo, and ostrich. A concern you had going in was
that the restaurant business is very risky. However, after some due
diligence, you discovered a common misperception about the restaurant
industry. It is widely thought that 90 percent of new restaurants close
within three years; however, recent evidence suggests the failure rate is
closer to 60 percent over three years. So, it is a risky business, although
not as risky as you originally thought.
During your interview process, one of the benefits mentioned was
employee stock options. Upon signing your employment contract, you
received options with a strike price of $45 for 10,000 shares of company
stock. As is fairly common, your stock options have a three-year vesting
period and a 10-year expiration, meaning that you cannot exercise the
options for a period of three years, and you lose them if you leave before
they vest. After the three-year vesting period, you can exercise the
options at any time. Thus, the employee stock options are European (and
subject to forfeit) for the first three years and American afterward. Of
course, you cannot sell the options, nor can you enter into any sort of
hedging agreement. If you leave the company after the options vest, you
must exercise within 90 days or forfeit.
Exotic Cuisines stock is currently trading at $17.89 per share, a slight
increase from the initial offering price last year. There are no markettraded options on the company’s stock. Because the company has only
been traded for about a year, you are reluctant to use the
page 549
historical returns to estimate the standard deviation of the
stock’s return. However, you have estimated that the average annual
standard deviation for restaurant company stocks is about 55 percent.
Since Exotic Cuisines is a newer restaurant chain, you decide to use a 65
percent standard deviation in your calculations. The company is relatively
young, and you expect that all earnings will be reinvested back into the
company for the near future. Therefore, you expect no dividends will be
paid for at least the next 10 years. A three-year Treasury note currently
has a yield of 1.5 percent, and a 10-year Treasury note has a yield of 2.6
percent.
1.
You’re trying to value your options. What minimum value would you
assign? What is the maximum value you would assign?
2.
Suppose that, in three years, the company’s stock is trading at $60.
At that time, should you keep the options or exercise them
immediately? What are some of the important determinants in
making such a decision?
984
3.
Your options, like most employee stock options, are not transferable
or tradeable. Does this have a significant effect on the value of the
options? Why?
4.
Why do you suppose employee stock options usually have a vesting
provision? Why must they be exercised shortly after you depart the
company even after they vest?
5.
A controversial practice with employee stock options is repricing.
What happens is that a company experiences a stock price
decrease, which leaves employee stock options far out of the
money or “underwater.” In such cases, many companies have
“repriced” or “restruck” the options, meaning that the company
leaves the original terms of the option intact, but lowers the strike
price. Proponents of repricing argue that since the option is very
unlikely to end in the money because of the stock price decline, the
motivational force is lost. Opponents argue that repricing is in
essence a reward for failure. How do you evaluate this argument?
How does the possibility of repricing affect the value of an employee
stock option at the time it is granted?
6.
As we have seen, much of the volatility in a company’s stock price is
due to systematic or marketwide risks. Such risks are beyond the
control of a company and its employees. What are the implications
for employee stock options? In light of your answer, can you
recommend an improvement over traditional employee stock
options?
1
We use buyer, owner, and holder interchangeably.
2
This example assumes that the call lets the holder purchase one share of stock
at $100. In reality, one call option contract would let the holder purchase 100
shares. The profit would then equal $3,000 = [($130 – 100) × 100].
3
Actually, because of differing exercise prices, the two graphs are not quite mirror
images of each other. The exercise price In Figure 17.1 is $100 and the exercise
price in Figure 17.3 is $50.
4
Our discussion in this section is of American options because they are more
commonly traded in the real world. As necessary, we will indicate differences for
European options.
5
This relationship need not hold for a European call option. Consider a firm with
two otherwise identical European call options, one expiring at the end of May and
the other expiring a few months later. Further assume that a huge dividend is paid
in early June. If the first call is exercised at the end of May, its holder will receive
the underlying stock. If he does not sell the stock, he will receive the large dividend
shortly thereafter. However, the holder of the second call will receive the stock
through exercise after the dividend is paid. Because the market knows that the
985
holder of this option will miss the dividend, the value of the second call option could
be less than the value of the first.
6
This graph assumes that, for each security, the exercise price is equal to the
expected stock price. This assumption is employed merely to facilitate the
discussion. It is not needed to show the relationship between a call’s value and the
volatility of the underlying stock.
7
Though this result must hold in the case of an American put, it need not hold for a
European put.
8
A full treatment of this assumption can be found in John C. Hull, Options, Futures
and Other Derivatives, 9th ed. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson, 2014).
9
This method is called linear interpolation. It is only one of a number of possible
methods of interpolation.
986
page 550
Short-Term Finance
and Planning
18
OPENING
CASE
Most often, when news breaks about a firm’s c...
Purchase answer to see full
attachment