Marketing Promotion Pricing Strategies Memorandum

User Generated

rat1460

Writing

Description

Please read the provided case "Beyond the Many Faces of Price: An Integration of Pricing Strategies" and write a 2 pages+ business memo based on the instruction file.

Unformatted Attachment Preview

Beyond the Many Faces of Price: An Integration of Pricing Strategies Author(s): Gerard J. Tellis Source: Journal of Marketing, Vol. 50, No. 4 (Oct., 1986), pp. 146-160 Published by: Sage Publications, Inc. on behalf of American Marketing Association Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/1251292 Accessed: 23-03-2020 05:50 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms American Marketing Association, Sage Publications, Inc. are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Marketing This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Gerard J. Tellis Beyond the Many Faces of Price: An Integration of Pricing Strategies The author reviews the field of pricing strategy and constructs a unifying taxonomy of the many str egies described in the literature. The taxonomy is based on the simple proposition that all the strategi have a common denominator-shared economies among buyer segments, across firms, or among prod ucts. The author presents the strategies in comparable terms, emphasizing the principles underlying e and demonstrating the relationship among strategies, the circumstances in which each can be used, the legal and policy implications of each. IN the last two decades the field of pricing strategyand reclassify the various pricing strategies in the lithas made great progress in the form of better the-erature. oretical explanations, more precise models, and in- The first objective of this article is to present a novative pricing strategies (see Nagle 1984 for onenumber of pricing strategies, some of which are simreview). However, the rich variety of pricing modelsplifications and others elaborations of strategies deand strategies developed in different time periods andscribed in the literature. A second objective is to state contexts has resulted in a multiplicity of labels, sev-their underlying principles in comparable terms and eral overlapping descriptions of strategies, and par- thus demonstrate their relationship to each other and tially obsolete typologies. Some pricing strategies aretheir practical applications. A third objective is to pronot yet presented adequately in the marketing litera-pose a classification of these strategies that is parsiture (e.g., price bundling, Stigler 1968; random dis- monious, logically derived, and enlightening to the counting, Varian 1980; or price signaling, Cooper anduser. Such a taxonomy could stimulate alternate Ross 1984) and others have not been developed for- schemes or general theoretical models or new applimally (e.g., price skimming and penetration pricing,cations of empirical models or new strategies (Hunt Dean 1951). A more pressing issue, however, is that 1983, p. 348-60). These objectives are carried out in the following because the principles underlying each strategy have order. First the classification is presented (though it not been presented together, it has not been possible to develop a unifying taxonomy of strategies that shows can be fully appreciated only at the end of the article). their relatedness or differences and immediately sug-Then each strategy is discussed in terms of a pricing gests the circumstances under which each can beproblem presented in simple numerical form. A paradopted. Thus there is a need to compare, rationalize,ticular pricing strategy is shown to be the only one that can resolve the problem, given the demand, cost, competitive, and legal environment. The theoretical Gerard J. Tellis is Assistant Professor of Marketing, University of Iowa. and welfare aspects of the strategy are summarized The article benefitted from the comments of Cathy Cole, S. Hariharan,and applications discussed. Finally, the relationship Timothy Heath, William Robinson, Raja Selvam, and four anonymous among strategies is explained. JM reviewers, as well as the editorial assistance of Barbara Yerkes. This article describes a set of normative pricing 146 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 Journal of Marketing Vol. 50 (October 1986), 146-160. This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms strategies. A pricing strategy is a reasoned choice from a set of alternative prices (or price schedules) that aim at profit maximization within a planning period in response to a given scenario. Thus, the article describes a set of ideal options one may choose and outcomes that result from such choices, assuming profit maximization by the strategist. Several important pricing topics are necessarily excluded from this discussion: managerial pricing approaches, price implementation, and price, cost, and demand estimation (see Monroe 1979 or Rao 1984 for excellent reviews). In the case of consumer behavior, however, allowances are made for non-optimal behavior. Its most important cause is incomplete information which leads to three types of behavior: consumers may purchase randomly, consumers may use a surrogate for an unknown attribute (e.g., price as a surrogate for quality), or consumers may evaluate choices incorrectly with resultant intransitivity in preferences. On the ba- sis of this hypothesis, Kahneman and Tversky (1979) developed prospect theory as an alternative to traditional utility theory and Thaler (1980, 1985) extended that work. Their work has important implications for pricing strategy. This article shows the impact of all three types of information deficiencies on pricing to search for it. Further, for some of them the opportunity cost of time exceeds the benefit of search, so that they are willing to purchase without full information. Second, at least some consumers have a low reservation price for the product. That is, some consumers are price sensitive or do not need the product urgently enough to pay the high price other consumers pay. Third, all consumers have certain trans- action costs other than search costs-for example, traveling costs, the risk of investment, the cost of money, or switching costs. The two dimensions-firm objectives and con- sumer characteristics-each with three categories yield nine cells into which the strategies discussed here are classified (see Table 1). Table 2 further compares and contrasts these strategies on several dimensions and is discussed in the concluding section. The real world, however, is more complex and several of the conditions listed (search costs, transaction costs, or demand heterogeneity) may occur jointly. Accordingly, in reality a firm may adopt a combination of these strat- egies. What is demonstrated in the proposed classification is the necessary conditions for each strategy, conditions that are jointly sufficient to classify them conveniently. Similarly, in the following discussion the problems define fairly simple scenarios where "other strategies. A Classification of Pricing Strategies The underlying principle in all the strategies discussed here is that the best strategy in certain circumstances is not apparent until certain shared economies or crosssubsidies are taken into account. In a shared econ- things are assumed constant" and only factors affecting the choice of a strategy are allowed to vary. The list of available strategies also is affected by the legal environment. Because of the potential for pricing abuses, especially against weak competitors or weak or uninformed buyers, Congress and the states have passed laws that regulate the pricing strategies firms can adopt. These laws generally ensure that there is no collusion among competitors, no deception of no explicit discrimination among indusomy, one consumer segment or product bears moreconsumers, of trial buyers, or no attempt to manipulate the competthe average costs than another, but the average price still reflects cost plus acceptable profit. The useitive of structure. Some of these laws rule out certain pricing options whereas others include new possibilsuch economies may be triggered by heterogeneity ities, and these effects are discussed in the appropriate among consumers, firms, or elements of the product place. The laws are not always fully explicit, but the mix. The pricing strategies can be broadly classified general motivation of the laws and the spirit in which into three groups based on which of these three factors affects a firm's use of shared economies: differential they have been interpreted by the courts indicate that pricing, whereby the same brand is sold at different no strategy should reduce the impact of competitive prices to consumers; competitive pricing, whereby forces unless it is to the benefit of consumers (Areeda prices are set to exploit competitive position; and 1974; Scherer 1980). product line pricing, whereby related brands are sold at prices that exploit mutual dependencies. The pricing objective of the firm thus constitutes the first dimension on which this classification scheme is con- Differential Pricing Strategies The price strategies discussed here all arise primarily because of consumer heterogeneity, so that the same The second dimension is the characteristics of product can be sold to consumers under a variety of consumers. Again there are three categories of inter- prices. The three strategies discussed refer to conest. First, at least some consumers are assumed to have sumer heterogeneity along three dimensions: transsearch costs. That is, consumers do not know exactly action costs that motivate second market discounting, which firm sells the product they want and they have demand that motivates periodic discounting, and search structed. Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 147 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~, , ,,_ TABLE 1 Taxonomy of Pricing Strategies Objective of Firm Characteristics of Vary Prices Among Exploit Competitive Balance Pricing Over Consumers Consumer Segments Position Product Line Some have high search Random discounting Price signaling Image pricing costs Some have low reservation Periodic discounting Penetration pricing Price bundling price Experience curve pricing Premium pricing All have special transaction Second market discountin costs TABLE 2 Comparison of Pricing Strategies Differential Pricing Competitive Pricing Product Line Pricing Penetration Second and Experi- Market Periodic Random ence Curve Price Geographic Price Premium Complemen- Criteria Discounting Discounts Discounts Pricing Signaling Pricing Bundling Pricing tary Pricing Characteristic of price strategy varies systematically over: Consumer segments Yes market Product mix No No Competitors in Characteristics of consumers Yes No No No No Only some High trans- with low action Yes No High search Some with costs: low reser- some un- vation reserva- physically tion price: informed price: about price senprice sensitive segprice sitive seg- segments No No No No Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes costs: separated No ment ment Only some High search High trans-Some prefer one prod- some un- costs: uct, oth- prefer basic prod- informed geographion quality; cally dis- ers, an- ucts at other: low prices prefer kets high qual- ric demand costs: portation uninformed tinct mar- High trans- action costs: risk aversiveness or store or asymmet- brand loyalty ity Product and cost characteristics Unused ca- Economies Economies unused of scale or unused capacity capacity pacity of scale or Economies Signaling experience, higher or unused costs or capacity suboptimizes or cheats on quality Higher pro- Perishable adjacent occasion duction costs in of scale or firm has Patents, Joint econ- product or purchase omies of superior technology scale across products; market; features with low cost increase relative to economies of scale or unused capacity price increase Variants Generic pricing, dumping Price skim- Variable ming, price merpeak-load chandispricing, ing, centsprice dis- off, cou- Limit pricing Reference crimina- pons pricing FOB, base point, uniform, zone, and freight pricing Mixed bun- dling, pure components, pure bun- dling - Captive pricing, twopart pric- ing, loss leadership tion, priority pricing Relevant legal con- Explicit price straints discrimina- ExplicitExplicit priceprice Predatory discrimina- tion illegal tion illegal discrimina- pricing il- tion illegal legal - Price collu- sion, explicit price discrimina- tion, pred- Explicit price discrimination, pure bundling illegal atory pric- ing illegal 148 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms - (Minimum) retail price mainte- nance ille- gal, tie-ins illegal costs that motivate random discounting.' These conditions enable a firm to discriminate implicitly in the as students, children, or new members. can meet specific defenses (Scherer 1980, p. 572; Similarly, for some countries the foreign market represents an opportunity rather than a threat if the same theory is applied. Often a firm's selling price or even current average cost in the home market may be higher than the selling price in the foreign market. However, if its variable costs are sufficiently below the selling price in the foreign market, the firm can export profitably at a price somewhere between the Werner 1982). In the consumer market, explicit price selling price in the foreign market and its variable costs. Aside from the special motivations for each type of discounting to be discussed hereafter, discounting in general has a sales enhancing effect, probably because consumers overweight the saving on a deal ("the silver lining," Thaler 1985) in relation to the cost still the latter strategy if the firm's selling price in the for- prices it charges its consumers. In industrial and wholesale markets, explicit price discrimination whereby a firm charges different prices to two competing buyers under identical circumstances is illegal under the Robinson-Patman Act's (1936) amendment of the Clayton Act (1914), unless the price-cutting firm discrimination would lead to the ill-will of consumers. The term "dumping" is sometimes used to describe eign market is below its average costs. The essential requirements for this strategy are that the firm have unused capacity and consumers have transaction costs so there is no perfect arbitrage be- tween the two markets. In terms of profitability, adIf the product were regularly at the discounted price, ditional revenues from the second market should exceed all increases in variable and fixed costs and loss many of these consumers may not buy it at all! incurred in buying the product at the discounted price. Second Market Discounting Consider a competitive firm that sells 100,000 units of a product at $10 each, when variable costs are $1 and fixed costs are $500,000 for a capacity of 200,000 units. The firm gets a request to sell in a new market such that there will be a negligible loss of sales in the first market and a negligible increase in fixed or variable costs. What is the minimum selling price the firm should accept? This is a classic problem in incremental costing and the solution is well known. The minimum ac- of profits from the first market. Note here that the first market provides an external economy to the second, because the latter market gets goods at a lower price than it would otherwise. (For this reason some economists are not critical of dumping. Others, however, stress that there may be long-term damage to the foreign economy from lost wages and production facilities.) The second market provides neither an economy nor a diseconomy to the first in the short run. Periodic Discounting ceptable price would be anything over $1, because anyConsider a firm faced with the following pricing price over variable costs would make a contribution problem. Average economic costs2 are $55 at 20 units to this ongoing business. Generics, secondary de-and $40 at 40 units. There are 40 consumers per period that are interested in its product. Half of them mographic segments, and some foreign markets pro-are fussy and want the product only at the beginning vide opportunities for profitable use of this strategy.of each period even if they have to pay $50 per unit. Often pioneering drugs are faced with competition from The other half are price sensitive and would take the product at any time but will pay no more than $30 identical but much lower priced generics after the ex-per unit. At what price should the firm sell its prod- piry of the patent. The pioneering firm has the options uct? of either maintaining its price and losing share or Initially it may seem that the firm cannot bring the dropping price and losing margin. The relevant stratproduct to market profitably because costs exceed acegy would be to enter the generic market segment with ceptable prices for each segment. However, in effect, an unbranded product and arrest loss of sales to that the firm can produce and sell profitably if it exploits segment without either foregoing margin or position the consumers' heterogeneity of demand by a strategy in the branded segment. The same principle also holds of periodic discounting. It should produce at the level for a firm changing to a mixed brand strategy after of 40 units per period at a cost of $40 per unit, price selling under a manufacturer brand only or a private at $50 at the beginning of each period, and systemlabel brand only. A second illustration of this strategy atically discount the product at the end of the period is the discounts to secondary demographic markets such to $30. In this way it would sell to the fussy con- sumers at the beginning and to the rest at the end of each period. Note that its average selling price is $40, 'There are also other motivations for discounting, the most common equals its average economic cost. being damaged goods, overstocking, or quantity purchases. These which discounts are not considered pricing strategies because they are merely adjustments for costs, often of an ad hoc nature. The term "price discrimination" has been used in the literature very broadly to mean 2The term "average economic cost" is used to mean all costs, procharging different customer groups prices not proportionate to costs duction and marketing, fixed and variable, plus acceptable profit difor the same or related products. It would cover almost all the stratvided by number of units. egies discussed here (Cassady 1946a,b; Monroe 1979; Scherer 1980). Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 149 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms This is the principle often involved in the temporal markdowns and periodic discounting of off-season fashion goods, off-season travel fares, matinee tickets, and happy hour drinks, as well as peak-load pricing for utilities (Hirshleifer 1958; Houthakker 1951; Steiner 1957; Williamson 1966). Similarly, this is the principle involved in the discounting of older models (Stokey 1981), the priority pricing of scarce products (Harris and Raviv 1981), and the strategy of price skimming, first suggested as one alternative for new products by Dean (1950a). Because of the circum- stances in which this discounting strategy has been used, it often is referred to by different names. How- ever, a more general label would be "periodic discounting," because of the essential principle under- lying this strategy: the manner of discounting is predictable over time and not necessarily unknown to consumers (unlike random discounting discussed next) and the discount can be used by all consumers (unlike second market discounting). An interesting issue in periodic discounting is that both segments of the market provide an external economy to each other.3 The first segment that pays the higher price can be viewed as providing a sort of "venture" price to the firm to produce the product, whereas the second segment can be viewed as providing a "salvage" price to the firm for unsold items at the period's end. This intuition suggests that, even if the demand for the product is not exactly known, a strategy of pricing high and systematically discounting with time is likely to ensure that the firm covers its costs and makes a reasonable profit. However, the pays $40 for the product. Then on average a consumer who searches and is informed saves $10 (40 - 30). Hence consumers whose opportunity cost of time is more than $10 should not shop and the rest should. Let us assume that at least some consumers search and others buy randomly. What strategy should the firm with an average economic cost of $30 adopt? The answer is a strategy of random discounts, which involves maintaining a high price of $50 regularly an discounting to $30. However, the manner of discount ing is crucial. It should be undiscernible or "random to the uninformed consumers and infrequent, so tha these consumers do not get lucky too often. The un informed consumers will not be able to second gues the price; they will buy randomly, usually at the hig price. In contrast, the informed will look around or wait until they can buy at the low price. In this wa the firm tries to maximize the number of informed at its low price instead of at a competitor's low price, while maximizing the number of uninformed at its high rather than its low price. Research on the intransitivity of preferences indicates some interesting twists to the appeal of discounts and coupons. First, searchers are likely to oversearch. They spend more time shopping than is justified by their gains, the result of what Thaler (1980) calls the "endowment effect." The real saving from the discounts is overweighted in relation to the opportunity cost of time. In contrast, nonsearchers are likely to undersearch for high cost products. This behavior can be explained by the psychophysics of pric- ing (Thaler 1980). Consumers relate the benefits of search to the cost of the good rather than to the cost of the time it takes to search. first segment provides a greater external economy than Most discounting today by specialty stores, de- the second, because it bears more of the production partment stores, services, and especially supermarkets costs. Random Discounting is of this type (referred to as "variable price merchandising" by Nelson and Preston 1966; Preston 1970). Out-of-store coupons or features are of this type Consider a firm that has a minimum average eco- unless motivated by periodic discounting, inventory nomic cost of production of $30. Assume a distri- buildup, or damaged goods. bution of prices for the same product between $30 The vast volume of business in this category has and $50 because there are several other firms with increased the importance of understanding the issues other cost structures and $50 is the maximum coninvolved. A static model of interfirm price variation sumers will pay for it. It takes one hour to search for the lowest price, $30. If a consumer does not search due to consumer search costs first was developed by but buys from the first seller, he/she may if lucky Salop and Stiglitz (1977) in their well-known piece, get a $30 seller but if unlucky may get a $50 seller. Further, assume consumers' opportunity cost of time ranges from $0 to well over $20 per hour. What is the best shopping strategy for consumers and the best pricing strategy for firms? For consumers, the prob- lem is fairly simple. Let us assume that the distribution of prices is such that on average a consumer who does not search and is uninformed about prices 3The discussion of welfare applies only to the competitive case as in the example described. Some of the applications of this strategy cited above have been to the monopolistic case, in which situation the price sensitive buyers are the primary beneficiaries. However, as the example illustrates, monopoly is not a necessary condition for periodic discounting, though some authors mistakenly say so. "Bargains and Ripoffs." Varian (1980) developed a dynamic model of random price variation by each firm, similar to the mechanism described in the last ex- ample. Since then a whole body of literature has developed pursuing various ramifications of this strat- egy. The basic condition for this strategy is heterogeneity of perceived search costs, which enables firms to attract informed consumers by discounting. All consumers know there is a distribution of prices and have the same reservation price. However, for high income individuals hunting for the lowest price may not be worth their time. For others the opposite holds. 150 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms The individual firm should adopt a strategy of random discounts if the increased profit from new informed consumers at the discounted price exceeds the cost arising from the uninformed buying at the discounted price plus the cost of administering the discount (see McAlister 1983 and Neslin and Shoemaker 1983 for profitability models). It is interesting to examine the implications of this strategy. First, note that the uninformed consumers provide a diseconomy to other uninformed consumers by currently pricing below com market and thus driving them o is a strategy of pricing low to h with the sole objective of establ conditions and subsequently rais tice is illegal under Section 2 of and to informed consumers. Inefficient firms that pro- the price mechanism developed by duce above $30 or efficient firms that price above $30 can exist because some consumers do not search. As pricing for adjacent market segm a result, prices vary, so that the informed must search for the lowest price. Similarly, the average price paid by the uninformed is higher as the proportion of uninformed increases. In contrast, the informed provide an external economy to the uninformed by encouraging the existence of low price firms, thus lowering the average price the uninformed pay. From a public policy perspective, all consumers as well as the efficient firms would benefit if some mechanism could be provided to disseminate price information in the market at relatively low cost. the Robinson-Patman Act of 1 have laws that forbid a firm fro for extended periods of time. A signaling,6 whereby a firm explo strategy, geographic pricing, Penetration Pricing Consider the periodic discounting following two modifications: the ec at 40 units is $30 and other compe enter the market with the same co should the firm price now? The firm could still adopt a st discounting, producing 40 units and selling to the first set of co the second at $30. Now, howeve cost price is $30, it would mak $10 per unit. Given this scenario, a Competitive Pricing This category covers a group of pricing strategies based primarily on a firm's competitive position. Penetration pricing and experience curve pricing attempt to exploit scale4 or experience5 economies, respectively, 4"Economies of scale" refers to the decline in average total costs with scale. This effect is generally attributed to superior technology or more efficient organization or cheaper purchases (Mansfield 1983; Palda 1969). Average total costs also are believed to increase beyond a certain point because of the difficulty of managing very large op- erations. 5"Experience curve" or "experience economies" refers to the decline in average total costs in constant dollars with cumulative volume (see Figure 1). Define Cl as average costs at volume V1, let V, hold for n, periods; define C2 as average costs at volume V2, let V2 hold for n2 periods. Then economies of scale are captured by the elasticity E, defined by C2 YlV2V be willing to come in and sell th an average price that is less tha $30. To preempt competition and firm would have to sell at $30 t The same logic underlies pen strategy first proposed for ne (1950a,b, 1951) as an alternative ing (or price skimming in Dea riodic discounting is obviously p even if its costs are lower than the modified example here), a immediate threat of competitive used for new products, penetrat V2 = VI, and when V2 # V, may still be d n, the time parameters. The strategic imp curve were best documented and populari ing Group (1972), though the issue was earlier (e.g., Alchian 1959; Arrow 1962 Keachie 1964). More recent theoretical c and economies of experience by the elasticity E, defined and by Robinson Lakhani (1975), Dolan and (1983). The decline in costs due to exper - n2 nl - e C, I V2 V1 (1) C V2i + Vli C2 _I ,1 (2) Cl i= number of factors, most importantly labo cess technology (see Abell and Hammon a complete list). Two important issues to b are that economies of experience can occu shown above) and that their decline gener stantly with cumulative volume. Beca n2 V2 nli V n, V, + creases at a faster rate in the first few ye n,VVI (e)n2V2t history, experience effects are most not Because of competitive pressures, prices 6The term is used here to mean firms sig Note that change in the scale of operation, measured by V2/VI, affects by price. It must be distinguished from the value of E, and Ee, which are therefore related. However, E, does strategies firms even may if use to "implic not cause Ee or vice versa. Moreover, unlike E,, Eethat is defined Beyond the Many Faces o This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms FIGURE 1 Effect of Experience Economies on Pricing Strategy strategy for firm A would be to price aggressivel even below current costs, at $3.75. This strategy h two advantages. First, it will be uneconomical for firm B, C, and D, which may have to leave the mark $ Firm A is then faced with less rivalry. Second, fi A can benefit from the share of the others and g experience more rapidly. Indeed, it would sell a A mulative volume of 12,000 units as early as yea Price and its costs would have dropped by then to $2 pe unit. In addition, the low price is likely to encour more consumers to enter the market, giving firm an opportunity to exploit economies of scale. A result the firm will soon be profitable again and to revenue and profits could be much higher in the ture. The strategy for the other firms is less clear general, unless there are other competitive adv tages, it is inadvisable for the others to start a pr war as they have a cost disadvantage to firm A. Experience curve pricing, like penetration pricin is an alternative strategy to periodic discounting. this strategy the consumers who buy the product earl in the life cycle gain an external economy from l buyers, as they buy the product at a lower price th 1 2 3 4 5 6 YEARS they were willing to pay. They get this discount, ho ever, because of economies of experience and activ or potential competition that forces prices down. The essential requirements for adopting an exp rience curve pricing strategy that experience served in the growth of are discoun fects are strong, the firm has more experience th solidation of manufacturers competitors, and that consumers are vari price sensitiv phase of the life cycle. A Typically, these conditions occur for nonessential d ing that has been closely stud rable goods in the early or growth stage, when a r erature is limit pricing (Scher atively large number of competitors are striving fo prices above costs but just l 0 2 I 4 6 i 8 J 10 I 12 I IJr0- CUM. VOL. (000) strong long-run position. The different sources new entrants. economies for penetration pricing and experience cu Penetration pricing is relevant only when the avpricing must be clearly understood, because the ci erage selling price can or does exceed the minimum cumstances in which they are applicable are often v average cost. Other essentials for penetration pricing similar strategy are price sensitivity on the part of some con- but the mechanisms for tracking costs sumers and the threat of competitive entry. In pricing pene- products are very different. tration pricing, unlike periodic discounting, the presence of the price sensitive consumers and of competition Price Signaling provides a benefit to the price insensitive segment, who can now buy the product at a price lower than Consider a market in which firms can produce products at two different quality levels, under the conthey were willing to pay. Experience Curve Pricing Assume a competitive market with experience effects as shown in Figure 1. There are four firms (A, B, C, and D), each with per period volume of 2000 units but the first having the most experience and average costs of $3.75 per unit. Current prices are $5 per unit. Consumers are price sensitive and react immediately to price changes. What would be a good pricing strategy for firm A? straint that the minimum average economic cost is $30 for the low quality product and $50 for the high quality product. Assume that, to avoid image con- flicts, each firm chooses to produce only one quality but may sell at either price, $30 or $50. Let us as- sume for convenience that there are at least a few firms selling the high quality product for $50 and the low quality product for $30. Consumers can easily find the lowest price (in negligible time), say by a phone call or consulting a price list. They generally prefer high quality, but it takes them 1 hour of study and consulting manuals to tell quality differences. Let these consumers have a distribution of opportunity Note that currently firm A makes more profit than costs of time as in the random discounting example. the others and that, given the projections, cost deWhat are consumers' shopping strategies and firms' pricing clines will be less prominent after year 6. A good strategies? 152 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Firms can choose among three pricing strategies (no firm would sell the high quality product at less than $50). First, they could produce the low quality product and sell it at $30. Second, they could produce the high quality product and sell it at $50. Third, they ports, is another illustration of consumers either buying randomly or using price to infer quality. There are some other variations of price signaling that firms can adopt to exploit consumer behavior in other circumstances. Image pricing, discussed sub- could sell the low quality product at $50, with the sequently, and reference pricing are two common ex- intention that some consumers who cannot tell high quality but want it will be fooled. The latter strategy is called "price signaling." Consumers also have three strategies. Those with low costs of time could study quality and buy the high quality product at $50. Those amples. In reference pricing, a firm places a high priced with high costs of time could adopt a risk aversive strategy and always buy the low priced product, or could buy the high priced product with the hope of though consumers who infer quality may buy it. Monroe and Petroshius (1981) document empirical support for consumers' use of reference prices. Kahneman and Tversky (1979) provide the rationale for this behavior in what they call the "isolation effect": a choice looks getting a high quality product. Extensive research in marketing has indicated that consumers may use price to infer quality (Monroe and Petroshius 1981; Olson 1977), but the equilibrium properties of such behavior in real markets have only recently been worked out (Cooper and Ross 1984; Tellis 1985). Three underlying conditions are necessary for price signaling to be an equilibrium strategy. First, consumers must be able to get information about price more easily than information about quality. Second, they must want the high quality enough to risk buying the high priced product even without a certainty of high quality. This motive is especially necessary because consumers underweight the value of uncertain events (the "certainty effect," Kahneman and Tversky 1979). Third, there must be a sufficiently large number of informed consumers who can understand quality and will pay the high price only for the high quality product. This third condition ensures a sufficiently positive correlation between price and quality so that those uninformed consumers who infer quality from price find it worthwhile to do so on average. The issue of pricing in the presence of quality variation and asymmetric consumer information is typical of durable goods, though not uncommon for services and nondurable goods where it may involve less risk. For durables, quality is an important attribute yet consumer information on quality is low because of the difficulty of determining quality by inspection, the large number of brands, and the high innovation rate relative to repurchase time (Thorelli model next to a much higher priced version of the same product, so that the former may seem more at- tractive to risk aversive uninformed consumers. The latter model serves primarily as a reference point, more attractive next to a costly alternative than it does in isolation. The strategy is sometimes adopted by retailers of durable goods. A more common variation is for firms to state that a product is on sale, with the "regular" sticker price adjacent, when actually the regular price is on for less than half the time. To minimize deception on the part of firms, several states now define minimum time periods for the regular price. In this context it is worthwhile to consider the wel- fare aspects of such strategy. The most important point is that all consumers would be better off if a mechanism could be devised to provide information on quality to the market at low cost. Second, those firms that sell the low quality product for the low price and those that sell the high quality product for the high price would also be better off if information on quality were disseminated, because they would not lose customers to firms that sell the low quality product at the high price. The last category of firms would vanish. There- fore, heterogeneous search costs on quality create benefits for some firms at the expense of others. Third, there could be many reasons for firms to sell the low quality product at the high price. Some could adopt such a strategy accidentally, others because they are inefficient producers, and still others because they intentionally cheat. Fourth, consumers who use price to infer quality may not necessarily be worse off. To the extent that obtaining information on quality is difficult for them, the correlation between price and quality is and Thorelli 1977). One result is the possibility of positive, and they prefer the high quality product, they consumers using price to infer quality. However, another result is that the correlation between price and quality is low (Tellis and Wernerfelt 1985) and con- may profitably use the high price to infer quality. In such a situation there is an external economy from the informed to the uninformed who gather information via the price mechanism. sumers in a market, who do not know the quality of competitive brands but find quality important. The purchase of a high priced wine by the casual buyer is a good example. The success of several high priced, inferior quality brands, as reported by Consumer Re- strategy of random discounting. Both are used in situations in which consumers have heterogeneous search costs, but differ on other dimensions. For price signaling, there must be quality differences among products, information on quality must be more scarce than sumers may often be mistaken. Price signaling is probably most common for new or amateur con- Note that price signaling is independent of the Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 153 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms that on price, and quality must be important to consumers; further, each firm need adopt only one price level always and at least some efficient firms are necessary to establish consumer trust in the price mech- anism. Geographic Pricing Consider two adjacent markets X and Y, of 20 con- sumers each, where all consumers have a reservation price of $50 for the product and incur a cost of more than $10 for purchasing the product in the adjacent market. A firm operating in market X is faced with free competitive entry and the following cost structure: the economic cost price for the product is $40 at 20 units and $30 at 40 units, with an added cost of $10 per unit to ship the product to the adjacent market. The cost of production is higher in market Y. What pricing strategy should the firm adopt? The firm should produce 40 units and sell to both markets at an average economic cost price of $35 ($30 + $10 x 20 - 40). To avoid competitive entry, the firm must set the average selling price over both markets at $35. However, the firm has several options for pricing the product to the two markets, called "geo- graphic pricing strategies," depending on the competitive condition in market Y. If the competitive price in market Y is above $40, the firm can sell the product at $30 in market X and $40 in market Y to reflect the transportation costs of $10 per unit to the latter market. Because price equals average costs, the price would be profitable yet ward off entry. This strategy is called "FOB." If the competitive price in market Y is a little over $35, the firm could sell at $35 in both markets and still achieve the same competitive effect. This strategy is called "uniform delivered price." Zone pricing is a strategy be- tween the two when more markets are involved. When using zone pricing, the firm would charge different prices for different zones depending on the transportation costs to each, but within each zone it would charge one price, the average of all costs to all points in that zone. Basing point is still another variation of uniform delivered price; the firm chooses a base point for transportation costs to points other than the point of production. If the competitive price is a little over $30 in market Y, the firm could sell profitably to both markets by pricing at $30 in market Y and $40 in market X. This strategy is called "freight absorption cost," because market Y bears none of the transportation cost it incurs for the product. In a monopolistic situation, the firm may absorb the transportation cost or pass it on to consumers in market X. However, in a com- being between price penetration and second market discounting (see Table 1). As in price penetration, in geographic pricing the firm seeks to exploit economies of scale by pricing below competitors in a second market segment. As a result, the second market generally provides a benefit to the first. However, in geographic pricing the two segments are separated by transportation costs rather than by reservation prices. In this respect, geographic pricing is similar to the strategy of second market discounting, where two markets are also separated by transaction costs. In second market discounting, however, the firm explicitly attempts to exploit the differences between the two segments, providing considerable savings to the second market. By contrast, in geographic pricing the firm attempts to minimize differences between the two markets by sharing or "absorbing" the transportation costs between them. In spite of these transportation costs and because of economies of scale, the second market does not provide a diseconomy and generally provides an economy to the first. Some of the geographic pricing strategies discussed may be illegal in certain circumstances. Three general principles can be used to guide policy in this respect. First, a firm should not discriminate between competing buyers in the same region (especially in zone pricing for buyers on either side of a zonal boundary) because such action may violate the Robinson-Patman Act of 1936. Second, the firm's strategy should not appear to be predatory, especially in freight absorption pricing, because such a strategy would violate Section 2 of the Sherman Act of 1890. Third, in choosing the basing point or zone pricing the firm should not attempt to fix prices among competitors because such action would violate Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Product Line Pricing Strategies Product line pricing strategies are relevant when a firm has a set of related products. In all of the cases considered, the firm seeks to maximize profit by pricing its products to match consumer demand. However, in each of these strategies, the nature of either the demand or the cross-subsidies varies among the firm's products. A firm uses price bundling when it faces heterogeneity of demand for nonsubstitute, perishable products. A firm uses premium pricing when it faces heterogeneity of demand for substitute products with joint economies of scale. Image pricing is used when consumers infer quality from prices of substitute models. Complementary pricing (including captive petitive market such as this one, all the transportation pricing, two-part pricing, and loss leadership) is used when a firm faces consumers with higher transaction costs are borne by market X. costs for one or more of its products. Geographic pricing strategies can be thought of as 154 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Price Bundling Assume a distributor of two films, "Romancing the Stone" and "Places in the Heart," is faced by the following demand for these films from two movie houses, Astro and Classic Theatres, that serve the same market. Maximum Prices For: "Romancing the Stone" "Places in the Heart" ($'000) Paid By: Classic Theatres Astro 12 25 18 10 What is the best pricing strategy for the distributor to adopt if we assume it cannot explicitly discriminate in price or use tying contracts (force a theatre to buy both movies)? An explicit price discriminating strategy, charging each distributor the most it will pay for each movie, would yield a total revenue of $65K, but this practice is illegal. Assume the buyers are sufficiently informed and the products perishable so that differential pricing by periodic or random discounting is not possible. A penetration strategy is to price the first movie at $12K and the second at $10K, but in that case total revenue is only $44K from both theatres (2 x (12 + 10)). A "pure components" strategy is to price the first at $18K and the second at $25K, for a total revenue of $43K. The best solution is to price the first movie at $18K, the second at $25K, and offer both at $28K for a total revenue of $56K. Note that Classic Theatres will take both movies at no more than $37K and Astro at no more than $28K. Thus both theatres will accept the package for $28K, which is the profit maximizing strategy. This strategy is called "mixed bundling" to contrast it with a pure bundling alternative in which case only the package is available for $28K. Pure bundling may be illegal as a tying contract (Scherer 1980; Werner 1982). The mixed bundling strategy has the added advantage of creating the reference price effect: the package is offered at a much lower price than the sum of the parts. The economics of price bundling was first analyzed by Stigler (1968) and further developed by Ad- ams and Yellen (1976), Telser 1979, Spence (1980), Paroush and Peles (1981), Phillips (1981), and Schmalensee (1984). Examples of such a strategy are the lower prices for season tickets, buffet dinners, packages of stereo equipment, and packages of op- in the purchase of durable goods is the purchase occasion, at which time it is in the interest of sellers to maximize revenues within consumers' demand sched- ule by price bundling. For example, consumers may buy automobiles once in 3 or 5 years. Each of those times is an opportunity for a firm to sell a maximum number of options by appropriate pricing. The strategy of price bundling must not be confused with that of "trading up," in which consumers are persuaded to buy more or higher priced models than they originally intended. As the numerical example shows, a passive strategy of correctly bundling the prices of related items is all that is needed to maximize profit. It is also in the interest of consumers to buy at the price bundle. Thus, all consumers and sellers are better off with the mixed bundling strategy than with the pure components strategy.7 Premium Pricing Consider a firm faced with the following pricing problem. There is free entry and average economic costs (for production and marketing) are $50 at 20 units and $35 at 40 units. At any volume, it costs the firm an additional $10 per unit to produce and market a superior version of the product. Assume that any fixed costs of marketing two products instead of one are negligible. Forty consumers per period are interested in its product. Half of them are price insensitive and want the superior version of the product even if they have to pay $50 per unit. The other half are price sensitive and want the basic version of the product but will pay no more than $30 per unit. In what version and at what price should the firm sell the product? As in the periodic discounting example, costs seem to exceed prices if the firm chooses to sell to only one segment or at only one price. However, it can solve its problem by a premium pricing strategy that exploits consumer heterogeneity in demand. It should produce at 40 units, half of which will be of the superior version, for an average economic cost of $40. It should sell the basic product for $30 and the premium for $50, for an average selling price of $40, at which price it is profitable and wards off entry. Relative to its costs, the firm takes a premium on its higher priced version and a loss on its lower priced version. However, by exploiting joint economies of scale and tions on automobiles. The basic requirement for mixed bundling is nonsubstitute (i.e., conlplementary or independent), perishable products with an asymmetric demand structure. Because the products are not perfect substitutes, it is possible to get consumers to buy both (or all). Because the products are perishable, the differential pricing strategies of periodic or random discounting are not feasible. The perishability of food items or seats for shows is apparent. The perishability 7In this example all cost issues are ignored, which could lead to at least three scenarios. One is a monopolistic situation in which the costs are sufficiently low that any of the pricing options would be profitable. The second is a cost situation in which only the mixed bundling option would be profitable. This then would hold either for monopoly or pure competition. The third is a situation in which costs are sufficiently low that any option would be profitable, but there is free entry so firms would use only the penetration pricing strategy ($10 for the first and $12 for the second movie) which is always the preferable option for consumers. Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 155 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms ferences by pricing substitutes differently, whereas in using price bundling the firm seeks to bridge segment differences by selling at the lowest common package price. The difference between premium pricing and price signaling is that in the latter each firm produces only one type of product, which is sold at different prices to differently informed consumers. In the former, a firm produces two types of products to exploit the pricing of some nondurable goods such as basic joint economies of scale and markets them to heterand specialty breads or common and exclusive perogeneous but fully informed consumers. fumes. A similar strategy is used for the pricing of The welfare aspects of premium pricing parallel alternate service plans such as term and preferred inthose of periodic discounting. The main difference is surance policies, front and rear auditorium seating, and deluxe and basic hotel rooms. As is well known in in the fact that in periodic discounting the strategy is carried out for any one brand and the price variation the case of autos, firms do not find their lower priced is over time; in premium pricing, the strategy holds models "very profitable," but typically make their for any one time and the price variation is over related profits on the premium versions. Often these premium models. As in the periodic discounting example, each versions differ from the basic only by features and segment here provides an external economy to the other; options, whose production costs generally are not high however, the advantage to the price sensitive segment enough to justify the higher markup. Why does the the heterogeneity of demand, it can profitably produce and sell the product. Premium pricing applies in a large number of circumstances in markets today. It is used in the pricing of durable goods, typically appliances, for which multiple versions differing in price and features cater to different consumer segments. It also could apply for is greater because they buy a product below its avfirm produce the lower priced version and why do other erage cost. firms not enter the market with only the higher priced version? The preceding explanation is based on hetImage Pricing erogeneity in demand and joint economies of scale. Notice that the firm, by using a premium strategy, By image pricing, a firm brings out an identical versells at exactly its economic cost price, which is comsion of its current product with a different name (or patible with a competitive market with free entry.8 No model number) and a higher price. The intention is to firm could enter and profitably produce only for the signal quality. This strategy is between price signaling price insensitive segment. and premium pricing in that the demand characterisPremium pricing also is used in retail, wheretics it are similar to those of price signaling and the cost enables retailers to carry some otherwise unprofitable aspects are similar to those of premium pricing (see products desired only by select segments. The pricing Table 1). Thus the firm uses the higher priced version of byproducts, though generally considered different to signal quality to uninformed consumers and uses from premium pricing, involves the same principle. the profit it makes on the higher priced version to subA byproduct may carry a cost of disposal to the firm, sidize the price on the lower priced version. Image and this may add to the price of the main product. In pricing differs from price signaling in that the prices some cases a byproduct may be worth much more than are varied over different brands of the same firm's it costs the firm to produce, and this advantage can product line. It differs from premium pricing in that be used to subsidize the price of the main product. differences between brands are not real but only in the The essential difference between premium pricing images or positions adopted. This strategy may acand price bundling is that the former applies to subcount for some of the variation in prices of alternative stitutes and the latter to complementary products. Both brands of cosmetics, soaps, wines, and dresses that require heterogeneity in demand, but in using prediffer only in brand names. mium pricing the firm tries to emphasize segment dif- Complementary Pricing Complementary 8In some markets oligopolistic or monopolistic situations exist, in which case a firm can market profitably only to the premium segment. gies-captive However, there are several reasons for marketing to both segments. ership. First, dealers, especially of high priced durables, are more likely to accept an exclusive dealing strategy if the manufacturer has a com- pricing includes three related stratepricing, two-part pricing, and loss lead- plete line of products. Second, with a complete line it is easier toCaptive pricing: Consider a firm that produces a du- develop brand loyalty, especially as consumers tend to buy better ver-rable good whose economic cost price is $100 and sions of durables with each subsequent purchase. Third, a low priced life span is 3 years. During that time the product needs basic version may be used to attract consumers into stores, and thensupplies that have an economic cost price of $.50 a motivate them to buy the higher priced versions. Since an early notemonth. All consumers are willing to pay at most $50 for the product and $2 per month for supplies. Asby Dean (1950b), there is an extensive literature on alternative theoretical models for premium pricing. However, without formal em- suming all buyers will keep on purchasing supplies pirical analysis it is not possible to determine which model is relevantregularly and the discount rate for future earnings is zero, what pricing strategy should the firm adopt? or what alternatives need to be developed (Katz 1984). 156 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Under the given assumptions, the firm would do well to price the basic product at $50 and the supplies at $2. The accumulated premium over the life of the product would equal $54 (3 x 12 x $1.5) and would more than compensate for the loss at the time of selling the basic product. In actually computing the minimum price of the product, the firm would have to include as costs a discount for future earnings and the risk that consumers would not purchase supplies. The firm also needs to consider the potential gains from this strategy. For example, consumers may not view the basic product they purchased as a sunk cost, and may try to "recover" their investment by buying the accessories and using it (the "sunk cost effect," Thaler 1980). Alternatively, they may get involved in the product and use it more than expected. This possibility has led some authors to label this strategy "captive pricing" (e.g., Kotler 1984, p. 529). An interesting question is whether consumers would buy the package with the product at $100 and the accessories at $.50 if they were informed they were incurring the same cost the other way around. Probably they would not. A consumer may be reluctant to incur a big immediate investment (a certain loss) for an un- certain future satisfaction ("the certainty effect," Kahneman and Tversky 1979), or may not have the funds for the purchase. In either case, the consumer has a "transaction cost," which the firm apparently absorbs. broken into a fixed fee plus variable usage fees (e.g., the pricing by telephone companies, libraries, health or entertainment clubs, amusement parks, and various rental agencies). The economics of two-part pricing has been studied by several researchers, more recently by Schmalensee (1982). In retailing, the corresponding strategy is called "loss leadership," and involves dropping the price on a well-known brand to generate store traffic. The drop in price should be large enough to compensate consumers for the transaction cost involved in making the extra trip, switching from their normal place of purchase, or foregoing the cheaper basket of prices they pay at the alternative store. However, in many cases the drop in price may not be exactly that high, primarily because consumers may see the price drop as a real gain while underestimating the transaction costs (Thaler 1985). Nevertheless, to ensure a success in this strategy, retailers normally feature several "super buys," nationally branded products sold below cost. Manufacturers of nationally branded products have always disapproved of loss leadership for two reasons. First, a product that is often available on discount may give consumers the impression that the quality is inferior. Second, specialty stores that depend on the branded products for their source of income may lose sales to discount stores and therefore cease to distribute the product. Manufacturers have sought to restrain loss leadership by a strategy of retail The chief restraint on the use of captive pricing for durable goods and accessories is that there are often no major shared economies in the manufacture of the basic product and its accessories. Thus, if the premium on the accessories is too high, marginal producers of the accessories may enter the market and drive down prices. In some circumstances, as in the automobile industry, the accessories are themselves produced by smaller firms. Consequently this strategy has limited importance unless consumers are source loyal and would like to buy supplies from the original source even at a higher price. In other circumstances, manufacturers hold patents or are the only source of the technology for the production of the supplies. In this case captive pricing is crucial for the success of the product. Bain (1956) refers to the superior position of these firms as "absolute cost advantages." In no circumstances may the firm bind the buyer to purchase the supplies from it. Such a strategy of tying contracts may be illegal under the Sherman Act of 1890 price maintenance. However, (minimum) retail price maintenance is now illegal under a federal statute, the Consumer Goods Pricing Act of 1975 (Scammon 1985; Scherer 1980; Werner 1982). The reverse case, maintaining maximum retail prices, is not illegal (Scammon 1985). This situation occurs when a retailer charges too high a price for a branded product over which it has exclusive or selective distributorship. In such a case the retailer may suboptimize the manufacturer's profits (Machlup and Taber 1960). The manufacturer can control this practice by advertising the "suggested (maximum) retail price" and then enforcing such a price during the advertizing period. High priced durable goods such as appliances and automobiles are examples of products for which this strategy is used. Complementary pricing is similar to premium pricing in that the loss in the sale of a product is covered by the profit from the sale of a related product. However, there are two important distinctions. First, premium pricing applies to substitutes and comple- or the Clayton Act of 1914 (Burstein 1960; Scherer mentary pricing to complements. Second, comple1980; Werner 1982). mentary pricing requires variation in transaction costs The well-known examples of captive pricing are razors and blades, cameras and films, autos and spare over the products whereas premium pricing requires parts, and videos or computers and software pack- variation in preferences over consumer groups. As a result there is no sharing of economies among cusages. In the case of services, this strategy is referred to as "two-part pricing" because the service price is tomer groups in complementary pricing. Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 157 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms An Integration and Comparison of Strategies The preceding discussion demonstrates the variety of pricing strategies available to a firm. The theory underlying some of them has only recently been analyzed in the economics literature, though they all have been discussed in some form in the marketing discipline. A major contribution of this article is that all these strategies are discussed on the same basis and are compared in a manner that is theoretically rich yet typologically simple. The most important contribution is that the strategies are shown to have a common denominator-shared economies. This proposition makes possible an enlightening classification of the strategies and a summarization of their underlying principles. a greater economy to the price insensitive segment. In geographic pricing, the lower the competitive price in the adjacent market, the higher the price and hence the greater the diseconomy borne by the home market. In the class of product line pricing strategies, the shared economies are primarily over the production or marketing of the products in the line. In image pricing, premium pricing, and complementary pricing, one product is sold at a "loss" which is then recovered from the higher price of a complementary product sold to the same segment or of a substitute product sold to a less price sensitive segment. In price bundling, there is an asymmetric demand by two consumer segments over two nonsubstitute products. A firm using the optimum price sells both products at the lower of the joint reservation prices. In this way the firm sells one The classification is based on two dimensions: the obproduct below the acceptable price of one segment, jective of the firm in exploiting these shared econ- but compensates by selling both products to both segments. In all of these cases the creative dimension of omies and the consumer characteristics necessary for each strategy (see Table 1). pricing is to identify the source and pattern of shared The relevance of the central idea of shared econeconomies that can be exploited for the benefit of the omies is summarized here with respect to Table 1. Aindividual firm and its consumers. more detailed explanation is given in the description Besides delineating the classification scheme, this of the welfare aspects of each strategy. In the class article compares and contrasts the various strategies of differential pricing strategies, one product is sold with closely related alternatives. In addition, a sumto two segments at different prices. By this means the mary comparison based on five criteria is presented in Table 2. These criteria are the characteristics of the firm exploits economies of scale and each segment strategy; the necessary consumer, product, and cost provides an economy to the other. In addition, in seccharacteristics; the relevant legal constraints; and the ond market discounting and periodic discounting, one segment buys the product at a higher price and in sovariants of this strategy. The table demonstrates that doing incurs more of the production costs so that the the multiplicity of names distracts from the essential product can be made available to the other segment similarity among the strategies and the common prinat its lower acceptable price. In random discounting,ciples that unify them. A small, theoretically based the searchers ensure that the product is available at aset of labels, like the one suggested here, enhances understanding and communication on the issues. lower price at random periods, thus providing a lower Besides the pedagogical and managerial benefits average price to the nonsearchers. from this presentation of pricing strategies, the theoIn the class of competitive pricing strategies, firms retical presentation suggests certain research avenues. sell one product to one or more market segments at One would be to review and further develop pricing the same price, but the pattern of shared economies models based on this classification scheme. Different is more complex. In price signaling, the searchers provide an economy to nonsearchers, who can get themodels then could be usefully compared, new uses for quality they desire (either high or low) at an accept-older models identified, and newer models developed. Another avenue would be to determine to what extent able risk of an error just by observing prices. In penthese different strategies are carried out in practice, etration, experience curve, and geographic pricing, the two segments provide a simple cost economy to eachthe types of firms that use particular strategies, and the factors that determine empirical success. A third other, enabling the firm to exploit economies of scale or experience. In addition, in penetration and expe- avenue is to determine whether the principle of shared economies is in fact the main explanation for these rience curve pricing the common price is that of the strategies, as is proposed here. more price sensitive segment, which therefore confers REFERENCES Adams, W. J. and J. L. Yellen (1976), "Commodity Bundling Abell, Derek F. and John S. Hammond (1979), Strategic Market Planning: Problems and Analytical Approaches. En- and the Burden of Monopoly," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90 (August), 475-98. glewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. 158 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Alchian, A. (1959), "Costs and Outputs," in The Allocation of Economic Resources, M. Abramovitz et al., eds. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 23-40. Areeda, Phillip (1974), Antitrust Analysis. Boston: Little, Brown & Company. Arrow, K. J. (1962), "The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing," Review of Economic Studies, 29 (June), 15573. Bain, Joe S. (1956), Barriers to New Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Boston Consulting Group (1972), Perspectives on Experience. Boston, MA: Boston Consulting Group, Inc. Burstein, M. L. (1960), "The Economics of Tie-In Sales," Review of Economics and Statistics, 27 (February), 68-73. Cassady, Ralph, Jr. (1946a), "Some Economic Aspects of Price Discrimination Under Non-perfect Market Conditions, Journal of Marketing, 11 (July), 7-20. (1946b), "Techniques and Purposes of Price Discrimination," Journal of Marketing, 11 (October), 135-58. Cooper, R. and T. W. Ross (1984), "Prices, Product Qualities and Asymmetric Information: The Competitive Case," Review of Economic Studies, 51, 197-207. Dean, Joel (1950a), "Pricing Policies for New Products," Harvard Business Review, 28 (November-December), 4553. (1950b), "Problems of Product-Line Pricing," Journal of Marketing, 14 (4), 518-28. (1951), Managerial Economics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Dolan, Robert, and Abel Jeuland (1981), "Experience Curves and Dynamic Demand Models: Implications for Optimal Pricing Strategies," Journal of Marketing, 45 (Winter), 52- and S. M. Petroshius (1981), "Buyers' Perceptions of Price: An Update of the Evidence," in Perspectives in Consumer Behavior, H. H. Kassarjian and T. S. Robertson, eds. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman and Company, 43-5. Nagle, Thomas (1984), "Economic Foundations for Pricing," Journal of Business, 57, 1, 2, S3-S26. Nelson, Paul E. and Lee E. Preston (1966), Price Merchandising in Food Retailing: A Case Study. Berkeley, CA: The Special Publications. Neslin, Scott A. and Robert W. Shoemaker (1983), "A Mode for Evaluating the Profitability of Coupon Promotions," Marketing Science, 2 (Fall), 361-88. Olson, J. C. (1977), "Price as an Informational Cue: Effect on Product Evaluations," in Consumer and Industrial Buying Behavior, A. G. Woodside et al., eds. New York: NorthHolland Publishing Company, 267-86. Oren, Shmuel S. (1984), "Comments on Pricing Research i Marketing: The State of the Art," Journal of Business, 57, 1, 2, 561-4. Palda, Kristian S. (1969), Economic Analysis for Marketing Decisions. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Paroush, J. and Y. C. Peles (1981), "A Combined Monopoly and Optimal Packaging Model," European Economic Review, 15 (March), 373-83. Phillips, O. R. (1981), "Product Bundles, Price Discrimination and the Two Product Firm," working paper, Texas A&M University. Porter, M. E. (1980), Competitive Strategy, Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitions. New York: The Free Press. Preston, Lee E. (1970), Markets and Marketing. Glenview, 62. IL: Scott, Foresman and Company. and E. C. Keachie (1964), "Cost Functions and Harris, Milton and Arthur Raviv (1981), "A Theory of MoProgress Functions: An Integration," American Economic nopoly Pricing Schemes with Demand Uncertainty," AmerReview, 54 (March), 100-7. ican Economic Review, 71 (June), 347-65. Rao, Vithala R. (1984), "Pricing Research in Marketing: The Hirsch, W. (1952), "Manufacturing Progress Functions," ReState of the Art," Journal of Business, 57, 1, 2, S39-S60. view of Economics and Statistics, 34 (May), 143-55. Robinson, Bruce and Chet Lakhani (1975), "Dynamic Price Hirshleifer, Jack (1958), "Peak Loads and Efficient Pricing: Models for New Product Planning," Management Science, Comment," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72 (August), 21 (June), 1113-22. 451-62. Salop, Houthakker, Hendrik (1951), "Electricity Tariffs in Theory andSteven and Joseph Stiglitz (1977), "Bargains and Ripoffs: A Model of Monopolistically Competitive Price DisPractice," Economic Journal, 61 (March), 1-25. persion," Review of Economic Studies, 493-510. Hunt, Shelby D. (1983), Marketing Theory, The Philosophy Scammon, Debra (1985), "Price Control (Minimum and Maxof Marketing Science. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, imum)," Journal of Marketing, 49 (Spring), 147. Inc. Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky (1979), "ProspectScherer, The- F. M. (1980), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Chicago: Rand McNally College Pubory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk," Econometrica, lishing Company. 47 (March), 263-91. Schmalensee, Richard (1982), "Commodity Bundling by SinKalish, Shlomo (1983), "Monopolist Pricing with Dynamic gle-Product Monopolies," Journal of Law and Economics, Demand and Production Cost," Marketing Science, 2 25 (April), 67-72. (Spring), 135-60. (1984), "Gaussian Demand and Commodity BunKatz, Michael L. (1984), "Firm-Specific Differentiation and dling," Journal of Business, 57, 1, 2, S211-S230. Competition Among Multiproduct Firms," Journal of BusiSpence, A. M. (1980), "Multi-Product Quantity-Dependent ness, 57, 1, 2, S149-S166. Prices and Profitability Constraints," Review of Economic Kotler, P. (1984), Marketing Management. Englewood Cliffs, Studies, 47 (October), 821-42. NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Steiner, Peter O. (1957), "Peak Loads and Efficient Pricing," Machlup, Fritz and Martha Taber (1960), "Bilateral MonopQuarterly Journal of Economics, 71 (November), 585-610. oly, Successive Monopoly, and Vertical Integration," Stigler, G. J. (1968), "A Note on Block Booking," reprinted Economica, 27 (May), 101-19. in The Organization of Industry, G. J. Stigler, ed. HomeMansfield, Edwin (1983), Principles of Microeconomics, 4th wood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc. ed. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. Stokey, Nancy L. (1981), "Rational Expectations and Durable McAlister, Leigh (1983), "A Theory of Consumer PromoGoods Pricing," Bell Journal of Economics, 12 (Spring), tions: The Model," Sloan School Working Paper #1457112-28. 83, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Tellis, Gerard J. (1985), "Do Prices Signal Quality: Theory Monroe, Kent B. (1979), Pricing: Making Profitable DeciMeasurement and Evidence," Working Paper #85-53, Colsions. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company. Beyond the Many Faces of Price / 159 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms lege of Business Administration, The University of Iowa. and Birger Wererfelt (1985), "The Price of Quality," Working Paper #85-52, College of Business Administration, The University of Iowa. Telser, L. G. (1979), "A Theory of Monopoly of Comple- mentary Goods," Journal of Business, 52 (April), 211-30. Thaler, Richard (1980), "Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1 (March), 39-60. (1985), "Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice," Marketing Science, 4 (Summer), 199-214. Thorelli, Hans B. and Sarah V. Thorelli (1977), Consumer ,I Information Systems and C Ballinger Publishing Comp Tversky, Amos (1969), "Int chological Bulletin, 76, 31 Varian, Hal (1980), "A Mode nomic Review (September Werner, Ray 0. (1982), "Mar preme Court, 1975-1981," Journal of Marketing, 46 (Spring), 73-81. Williamson, Oliver E. (1966), "Peak-Load Pricing and Optimal Capacity Under Indivisibility Constraints," American Economic Review, 56 (September), 810-27. -AMA a MEMBER S What does being an American Marketing Association member mean to you? The list goes on and on... H * A subscription to Marketing News (26 issues) * A copy of the Marketing Services Guide & AMA Membership Directory (600+ pages) * A reduced rate for the Journal of Marketing Research & Journal of Marketing * Group Insurance Program * Discounts on business publications such as Fortune, Business Week, Working Woman, Forbes, Harvard Business Review. I P * Academic Placement Service * Access to the AMA information center-3,500 books, 90 periodicals, and a clipping file of current literature * Conferences-at least 20 continuing education events are held annually * Local chapter programs & activities ...and on. Contact the AMA Membership Department and find out about joining one of the most prestigious organizations in the marketing world. American Marketing Association 250 S. Wacker Drive, Suite 200 Chicago, IL 60606 312/648-0536 l 160 / Journal of Marketing, October 1986 This content downloaded from 134.154.190.2 on Mon, 23 Mar 2020 05:50:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms AMERICAN AMRKETING ASOCIATION Guidelines for Toolbox Exercise #2: Pricing Prepare your Toolbox Exercise #2 in four+ pages, as a business memo. Due 3/26 1. Read Gerard Tellis, Beyond the Many Faces of Price: An Integration of Pricing Strategies, AMA, 1986. Find in CSUEB Library: Search JSTOR 2. Select three specific pricing strategies as described in the article. 3. Then identify and research two additional, distinct pricing strategies not discussed by Tellis. 4. For each of your five chosen pricing strategies, - Define in your own words the pricing strategy, and how the pricing strategy is intended to fit with overall marketing strategy. - Identify one current example of an application for each of your five chosen pricing strategies. Your examples may come from our text, other scholarly articles, corporate or non-profit websites, business journals, advertising and promotion for a product or service. -Explain, for each of your five example strategies: a) the product or service offer; b) your analysis of the pricing strategy, referencing your info sources; c) impact of the pricing strategy on customers, the brand and competition - Develop conclusions about the success of pricing strategies you’ve identified. - Cite references you have used at the end of your Toolbox Exercise. - Include specific evidence for pricing applications: cite webpage, ad, journal, etc. - Include photos and/or screen shots to illustrate at least distinct three pricing examples. Submit assignment on Blackboard ©2020 Jeffrey E. Newcomb Red Widget Strategies Toolbox Exercise #2: Pricing Rubric ©2020 Jeffrey E. Newcomb Red Widget Strategies
Purchase answer to see full attachment
User generated content is uploaded by users for the purposes of learning and should be used following Studypool's honor code & terms of service.

Explanation & Answer

Attached.

Running head: PRICING STRATEGIES

1

Pricing Strategies

Student Name
Institution Affiliation

PRICING STRATEGIES

2
Memo

TO:
FROM:
DATE:
SUBJECT: Pricing Strategies
Pricing strategies
Pricing strategies helps entrepreneurs on how to make prices decisions for the products.
The three main pricing strategies discussed in the morning article are geographical pricing,
product line pricing and penetration pricing strategies. The other pricing strategies not discussed
here include psychological pricing and pricing for promotions.
Price penetration
To begin with, the price penetration strategy is a price set by a company when penetrating
a new market (Tellis, 1986). This strategy is used by entrepreneurs to gain market share, and
most of them use it by either providing some services for free or keeping low prices d...


Anonymous
Very useful material for studying!

Studypool
4.7
Trustpilot
4.5
Sitejabber
4.4

Similar Content

Related Tags