The Political System An army official with his back to the camera salutes a large
group of service men.
iStockphoto/Thinkstock 8 Learning Objectives
After reading this chapter, you should be able to:
Define politics.
Analyze the political structure of bands.
Analyze the political structure of chiefdoms.
Analyze the political structure of states.
Analyze politics, law, and crime in the United States.
Discuss the influence of minority status on political power.
Define the basic mechanisms of social control: socialization, religion, rewards, gossip and
Discuss the common peaceful means for conflict resolution.
Discuss the use of power as a means of conflict resolution.
Define and explain crime.
Discuss the various means by which internal conflict is commonly addressed.
Define and explain rebellion and revolution.
Nowhere is political power—the ability to make and implement decisions about
public goals—shared equally by every member of society. Whether people share
power broadly throughout the entire community, divide power between their
family organization and specialized associations, or place power in the hands
of fulltime governmental officials depends largely on the size and complexity of
their societies. But whatever their political form, societies always have some
system for maintaining social order and reestablishing order when rules have
been broken. Some combination of childhood socialization, values, morality,
religion, rewards for conformity, and threats of punishment is used everywhere
to create an ordered society, although never with perfect success. When conflicts
do arise, there are a variety of ways, both peaceful and violent, by which people
seek to re-establish an orderly life.
8.1 Types of Political Orders
According to Swartz, Turner, and Tuden (1966), politics is the way in which
power is achieved and used to create and implement public goals. As such,
politics is involved in organizing and controlling human social behavior. It is
through its political system that a society exercises power to maintain order
internally and to regulate its relations with other societies. Those to whom the
right to power is delegated are said to have authority, or the right to legitimately
use force or threaten the use of force to achieve social goals. In the study of
politics, it is important to consider how power is delegated, as not every use of
power in society is legitimate.
Anthropologists have noted a variety of ways in which political power is channeled
in different societies. In societies that have only a small number of specialized
occupations, politics may be handled without the existence of a government: that
1
is, a body of officials who have the authority to create and administer a system
of laws, formal rules that are binding on members of society at large. Complex
societies have full-time political systems with officials who monopolize the legal
authority to govern others. Simpler societies make use of other mechanisms for
creating and implementing common goals. For instance, governing authority
may be vested in the local community, in families, in voluntary associations,
or in officials whose authority is limited to those areas not governed by the
community, family, or voluntary associations. See Figure 8.1. Figure 8.1: Types
of political orders
Click here to view alternate text. Bands: Government by Community
Societies in which people survive by foraging for wild foods in small local groups
are called bands. They consist typically of 50 or 60 people who cooperate in
economic activities and often share kinship ties. As late as the second half of
the 19th century, bands were found in remote areas, such as subarctic North
America, Greenland, and Siberia, as well as isolated parts of South America,
Australia, and Southeast Asia. However, there are no known band societies
today that exist in their traditional political form.
In band societies, most political problems affect the entire local group such that
it is generally the seat of legal authority. When a legal problem arises, the entire
community will discuss the issue in a community gathering until everyone has
had ample opportunity to express an opinion. The consensus that evolves out of
the give and take of group discussion is the band equivalent of law.
For example, the handling of homicide by the 19th-century Inuit of the northern
coasts of North America illustrates the legal role of the community in a band
society. The Inuit occupied a harsh environment that placed heavy demands on
them. In a territory that offered few plant foods, hunters were under great stress
to provide for their families. Game included some rather formidable animals
such as the polar bear and large sea mammals that were not easily taken. It is
little wonder that successful Inuit hunters were strong-willed and aggressive men.
In spite of rules of etiquette that demanded humility, politeness, and generosity,
tempers sometimes got out of hand, and violent deaths following disputes about
food and women were not rare.
Homicides were often dealt with by the families of the deceased. Revenge killings
were legitimate, but might in turn lead to vengeance by the original killer’s kin.
To avoid this, ultimate legal authority was vested in the community as a whole,
which dealt with aggressive repeat offenders who were seen as threats to the
common welfare. Boas (1888) described the role of community law enforcement
among one group of Inuit:
There was a native of Padli by the name of Padlu. He had induced the wife
of a native of Cumberland Sound to desert her husband and follow him. The
deserted husband, meditating revenge . . . visited his friends in Padli, but
before he could accomplish his intention of killing Padlu, the latter shot him.
. . . A brother of the murdered man went to Padli to avenge the death of his
2
brother; but he also was killed by Padlu. A third native of Cumberland Sound
who wished to avenge the death of his relatives was also murdered by him.
On account of all these outrages the natives wanted to get rid of Padlu, but
yet they did not dare to attack him. When the pimain (headman) of the
Akudmirmiut learned of these events he started southward and asked every man
in Padli whether Padlu should be killed. All agreed; so he went with the latter
deer hunting . . . and . . . shot Padlu in the back. (p. 582)
Because the entire community had acted as a judicial body and authorized the
killing, it was a legal execution, and they had no need to fear any retribution by
Padlu’s relatives.
As might be expected, band societies have no need for sufficient resources
to support any full-time educational, economic, religious, military, judicial,
legislative, or executive specialists. All leadership is charismatic. That is, a man
or woman becomes a leader in some activity because of a personal talent in that
area. Leadership also is unofficial; it is maintained only so long as a person
demonstrates the qualities of excellence that draw a following. Charismatic
leadership confers no formal authority, no power to coerce. A leader can only
lend advice, persuade, or take the initiative. Coming from a man or woman of
respected abilities or wisdom, the advice or action is apt to be followed by others.
The leader in the hunt, for example, is likely to be a man of proven ability in
locating, tracking, and capturing game; a leader in political matters is respected
because of his broad experience and proven wisdom. In both cases, however, as
abilities decline, so does the leader’s following. Tribes: Government by Families
and Associations Pakistani officials have a discussion outside.
Steve Raymer/National Geographic Stock
Political systems exist to create a mechanism for social control and to promote
group harmony. In this scene, officials and tribal leaders discuss agricultural
plans.
Societies with simple food domestication technologies that support local populations and that are small enough to need no full-time governmental authorities
are known as tribes. Tribal societies are found in such places as North America,
New Guinea, Melanesia, North America, India, and Afghanistan.
Within tribes, legal authority is held by descent groups, such as lineages and
clans (see Chapter 6), of the local group and by local voluntary associations (or
sodalities). These are groups whose members are drawn from at least several of
the families of the community and that carry out governing, military, policing,
and economic functions. Sodalities such as a council of elders may, for instance,
be made up of the heads of each of a community’s descent groups. Such decisionmaking bodies are effective because their membership is recruited from many kin
groups so that the views of most or all of the community are well represented.
One common type of sodality is based on age. These age-graded associations are
voluntary associations whose membership is limited to persons of a particular
3
age category. They often play a role in such things as the military defense
of the community and in policing the community itself in matters that do
not traditionally fall within the realm of family law. By contrast, familial legal
authority typically rules in domestic matters such as the contracting or dissolving
of marriage and the punishment of family members for violation of one another’s
rights.
The tribes of the North American plains illustrated well the political role of
voluntary associations. Each community typically had a dozen or so military
societies. In some tribes, young men graduated from one society into the
next as they aged; in others, they had to choose which they would join. The
military associations exercised legal authority as governing agencies by preserving
order during hunts and while camp was being moved, as well as by punishing
lawbreakers. But they also performed social, recreational, and economic roles
in hosting feasts and dances, holding intersociety competitions, keeping tribal
traditions, and providing information about the location of buffalo herds. Policing
Role
Among Plains Indians, each military society usually held policing authority for
only 1 year, so that this responsibility was rotated among the associations of
a community, and no one monopolized the right to police power. Enforcement
of tribal laws by military societies was also limited to crimes that harmed the
community welfare. Thus, on communal buffalo hunts, someone who began to
shoot too soon and frightened the herd away before others were prepared was
likely to be punished. The emphasis was on making the culprit an example
to discourage similar behavior by others. Public punishments included the
destruction of a wrongdoer’s property, banishment from the camp, and death.
The Plains Indians relied heavily on the migratory buffalo that passed through
their territories each year, and competition for this valuable resource brought
the highly mobile, horseback-hunting tribes into recurrent conflict. The military
associations protected their communities against other plundering tribes. The
greatest defenders of the tribe in each military society were rewarded with honor
and the plunder of war. In ceremonial meetings, these warriors recounted their
exploits in battle, and it was from among these men that more formal political
leaders were selected for the tribe. Social Roles
Social Structure of the Ache Indians Among the Ache, democratic principles
hold the group together. There is no designated chief, and leaders tend to arise
naturally.
How does decision making take place in the Ache tribe, and what factors make that decision-m
Plains military societies also played an important role in public recreation. They
performed dances as public exhibitions and generally interacted with the audience
in their celebrations. For their own members, the military associations provided
fraternal camaraderie and a place in which deep friendships could evolve.
4
As in bands, leadership in tribes is charismatic. It is achieved by an individual’s
personal ability to convince others that his or her unique qualities make him
or her especially worthy of being followed. Thus, leadership is based on skill
rather than the power of an inherited status. By and large, tribal society is
egalitarian like the band society, in that every individual has more or less equal
opportunity to obtain the necessities of life and the esteem of others through
leadership activities. Leaders also include the charismatic entrepreneurs who
stimulate local economic productivity (see bigmanship in Chapter 9). Chiefdoms:
Government by Officials
A society that unites a number of villages under the legal control of a government
that recognizes the right of families to exercise some autonomous legal authority
is a chiefdom. These types of societies are found in North America, Polynesia,
parts of Africa, and ancient Hawaii. Although a chiefdom’s governmental official
(called a chief) can legitimately use force in matters that concern the common
welfare, kinship groups exercise a great deal of legal autonomy. Chiefdoms
share some similarities with bands and tribes. For instance, laws that govern
marriage and divorce are typically matters of family law, just as they are in
bands and tribes. Similarly, the enforcement of laws concerning petty theft is
often a responsibility of kinship groups in chiefdoms, as in bands and tribes.
However, major crimes that concern the entire community, such as grand theft,
homicide, or insults to the dignity of a chief, are typically punishable by the
government officials who have authority over nonrelatives in legal matters. Thus,
chiefdoms have a true professional government, but one whose officials do not
monopolize all legal authority to govern society. Their authority is balanced
by that of each community’s kinship groups, which govern themselves in those
areas that most directly affect them.
Each community in a chiefdom is likely to have a chief who acts as its political
head, and groups of villages are usually unified under a district chief of higher rank
than the local village ones. In some legal matters, members of the community
may expect the chiefs or their delegated representatives to play the role of
mediator between the conflicting parties, with the goal of re-establishing peaceful
relations. In other cases, the chief may have the authority to determine guilt or
innocence and exact punishment for an offense without consulting the members
of the offender’s family. The position of chief is therefore a true office, and its
holder has authority to legitimately wield power over others with whom the chief
has no known kinship ties.
The office of chief is most often hereditary, although which relative of a deceased
chief will inherit the office may be decided by the surviving family members. In
some cases, the community as a whole may have some say in the selection of the
new chief from the group of possible heirs. Chiefdoms are typically theocratic
societies in which the office of the chief is legitimized by both religious and
secular authority. Indeed, some of the higher-ranking political officials may be
considered sacred.
In chiefdoms, the everyday functions of government include military defense,
5
local community policing, judicial activities, and drafting labor for public works
projects. Probably the most important function of chiefs, however, is economic:
to redistribute goods, provide services, and collect taxes. All families in the
community are expected to contribute a portion of their annual produce to the
warehouse. The chief then sees to it that these goods are redistributed, generally
at community feasts or festivals, to those most in need. A chief’s power and
prestige are often directly proportionate to his or her generosity. Indeed, the
level of gift giving expected of a chief may exceed the total contributed by other
families, so that the wealth of the chief’s family is gradually drained to benefit
less prestigious families.
Simple chiefdoms lack true social classes in which people’s rank depends on
the importance of their occupations. But neither are they egalitarian, as their
kinship groups are ranked in a social hierarchy in which some kin groups have
greater social power and prestige than others. For this reason, chiefdoms are
sometimes called rank societies (Fried, 1967; Service, 1962, 1978). Political
offices are usually inherited so that they remain within certain families, and the
highest-ranking families normally have control over the most important political
offices.
Beyond the superior social rank of chiefs’ families, some chiefdoms may develop a
true class distinction between chiefs and commoners that cuts across communities
(Earle, 1978). These complex chiefdoms also develop specialization in leadership
roles and a more centralized political hierarchy. According to Henry T. Wright
(1987), the political organization of chiefdoms varies in complexity along a
continuum. In simple chiefdoms, political control is in the hands of a local
elite, and there is only one level of political authority above that of the local
community. Complex chiefdoms are those in which the competition for leadership
at the higher level has created a class of chiefly competitors. As a result, these
chiefdoms “characteristically cycle between one and two levels of [political]
hierarchy above the level of the local community” (p. 43). In complex chiefdoms
the community where the paramount chief resides is larger than those of the
ordinary chiefs, partly because it is also the residence of his followers, who make
up his power base, and partly because it is a center for major social rituals.
Complex chiefdoms also have settlements of intermediate size that are controlled
by subordinate chiefs. It is in the smallest settlements, however, that the primary
work of subsistence production is done.
Those who belong to the chiefly class occupy their own segregated neighborhoods
within their communities or live in separate communities reserved for the noble
group. Chiefs are also buried in segregated community locations, often near
where major rituals occur and in burial grounds that are much more ornate than
those of commoners. The economic role of chiefs as managers of redistribution
shifts in complex chiefdoms from the distribution of goods to all families within
the community to the extraction of tribute from the common class in producing
communities and the redistribution of some of this tribute to the lower chiefs.
As chiefdoms increase in complexity, the redistributive goods exacted as tribute
6
shift from basic subsistence goods to commodities produced by specialists. These
economic specialists, who produce prestige goods—which are not available to
commoners—may be supported either by the food producers in their communities
or by the chiefs with payments gained from the tribute paid by the food-producing
class. The Rwala Bedouins: A Pastoral Chiefdom
According to Musil (1928), the Rwala had the largest and most powerful tentdwelling Bedouin chiefdom of the northern Arabian Peninsula. Although much
of their life was organized around the concept of kinship, the Rwala also had
officials with authority beyond the boundaries of their own kin. These chiefs or
sheikhs were officers whose positions were inherited within particular patrilineal
lineages. In addition to local sheikhs whose authority was felt throughout an
entire camp, there were regional chiefs as well, whose authority derived from a
lineage of greater prominence than those of the local chiefs. There was also a
paramount chief or sheikh, often called a “prince,” of all the Rwala. His main
duties were to conduct relations with the national government and with chiefs
of other Bedouin peoples, but he had little power over the internal politics of
the Rwala themselves.
Life in the camps was largely governed by kinship. Each man saw himself as the
center of a group of relatives, or kindred, known as the ahl. A man’s ahl consisted
of all his sons and their sons, his father and grandfather, and their brothers. This
group of male relatives had strong obligations to him and could bear the guilt
for his misdeeds. People were also organized into larger kinship groups called
feriz that included relatives who traced their ancestry through their fathers back
to a common male ancestor. Marriages were preferably within one’s feriz. In
particular, a man was encouraged to marry his father’s brother’s daughter or his
father’s father’s brother’s son’s daughter. A woman could marry no other man
unless her designated cousin waived his prior claim. The marriage preference
system counteracted the fragmenting effects of the Bedouin pastoral adaptation
to a desert environment, kept inheritable property from being dispersed, and
increased familial solidarity (Barth, 1954; Murphy & Kasdan, 1959).
The Rwala made their living by herding camels, which could provide transportation, milk for food, and hides and hair for manufacturing items. Camels were
traded to merchants in return for cash, weapons, clothing, and other necessities.
Trade was important, for the desert environment did not permit the Bedouins
to be completely self-sufficient.
Warfare, which consisted most often of surprise night raids on the enemy camp,
was a central fact of Rwala life and tinged many other aspects of their culture.
The main reason for warfare was to retrieve animals that had been stolen.
Weaker groups of Bedouins and villagers paid protection tribute (khuwa) to
more powerful ones such as the Rwala. The receiver of this protection “tax” was
bound to protect those who paid it and to restore any property that was stolen
from them by raiders. The Rwala enjoyed war because it was an opportunity
not only to win booty but also to display their skill and courage. Yet, 80% of
Rwala men died as a result of warfare, such that there were few elderly men.
7
Blood feuds were also common among the Rwala. Kin were obligated to avenge
the murder of a relative, and the murderer’s kin shared the guilt to the third
generation. The avengers therefore could take the life of a relative of the actual
culprit, should they find one before finding the murderer. Vengeance of this kind
was legitimate, a matter of family law. Guilty parties were not permitted to
defend themselves against avengers, but instead had to seek the protection of a
powerful sheikh who aided them in reaching a traditional place of refuge, where
they stayed until the avengers agreed to accept a blood price of horses, camels,
and weapons to compensate them for the death.
Today, the Bedouin, who number about 5 million, live a more settled life. Camels
for the most part have been replaced by Toyota trucks for transportation, and
tents have given way to cinder-block houses. Sheep and goat herds remain
an important source of livelihood for many Bedouin, but other occupations
and sources of income have also been adopted. Some engage in dry farming.
Others derive income from the tourist market. Members of the older generation
sometimes complain that younger people know too little about herding and are
only skilled at repairing trucks and televisions. States: The Official Monopoly of
Law
Because chiefdoms vary in their degree of social complexity and the power of
their governments, the social differences between a complex chiefdom and a
small state society may be slight. The defining difference is essentially one of
political ideology: a state is a political unit in which a centralized government
monopolizes the right to exercise legal force and control the affairs of local
communities. It has power to levy taxes, pass laws, and draft people into work
or war. Law
The principle that a state monopolizes the legitimate use of force is well illustrated
by Ashanti law. The Ashanti, described by Rattray (1923, 1929), made up a
West African state in what is now Ghana. The Ashanti state was ruled by a
divine king who, like Louis XIV of France, represented the very source of the
state’s authority. So sacred was the king’s personage that cursing him was
punishable by a heavy fine. Indeed, to curse the king was such a terrible thing
that it could only be spoken of by the euphemism, “to bless the king.”
Only the divine king or his duly authorized representatives had the authority
to use any force. Because any crime involved the use of force, it was, in a
sense, theft of the king’s authority and an insult to the sacred ancestors that he
represented. All crimes were therefore punishable by death.
The view that crimes were punishable primarily because they undermined the
authority of the state and only secondarily because they victimized others led to
another interesting aspect of Ashanti law. Like murder, suicide involved taking
the life an Ashanti and was also a contemptible affront to the king and the
ancestors. So the body of a suicide was tried and, if found guilty, decapitated.
In this way, Ashanti law symbolically demonstrated the sanctity of the state’s
authority. Odd as this legal custom may seem to North Americans, it is not very
8
different in principle from U.S. and Canadian customs in which persons who
attempt suicide may be confined in mental hospitals by judicial order for having
tried to kill themselves. Although North Americans speak of such confinement
as “hospitalization” for “treatment of a mental disorder,” the symbolic aspects of
the customs are similar. Both the Ashanti and North Americans punish suicide
offenders through a judicial process.
In addition to legal aspects, the chiefdom and the state society differ in their
subsistence activities. Specifically, states have more intensive agriculture based
on innovations in agricultural technology. While the plow and draft animals are
almost always present in societies that support a state-level political organization,
these societies also use other agricultural technologies. Irrigation systems, for
example, play such a major role in the agriculture of most states that one scholar,
Karl Wittfogel (1957), has suggested that it was the need to control and regulate
water resources that led to the rise of the world’s first states. This view has not
been widely accepted because it overemphasizes the single factor of irrigation
at the expense of other influential factors, such as population growth, trade,
diplomacy, and warfare. But it reminds us that irrigation was an important
technological development in increasing the productivity of the state’s subsistence
activities.
Robert Carneiro (1970) suggests that states arise in circumscribed environmental
zones—areas surrounded by mountains, deserts, or other natural barriers to
easy emigration—when population growth causes increased social competition
for natural resources. This competition leads to social stratification and the
domination of some groups by others. Centralized political power creates elites
who are able to exact tribute and taxes from the dominated groups. Circumscribed habitats make it difficult for those who are losing in the competition to
withdraw to other areas. Once states develop, they expand at the expense of
neighboring chiefdoms, tribes, and bands, whose smaller populations make them
less powerful. Members of a state society may number in the millions, owing to
the food supply provided by intensive agriculture. People may live in densely
packed towns and cities in which little or no agriculture may be practiced, or in
smaller, rural communities that produce particular kinds of food, which can be
exchanged for the nonagricultural products of the larger communities.
While Carneiro emphasized environmental and population-related factors to
explain the emergence of states, his ideas do not apply to early states in such
places as East Africa and Polynesia. Proposing a more comprehensive model,
Claessen (1996, 2000) argues that additional factors—such as economy, demography, conflicts, and ideology—have been integral to state formation. For example,
he argues that the development of early states was supported by a specific
ideology that explains and supports governmental hierarchy and social inequality
(such as, the division of society into rulers and the ruled). Early State Societies
It is generally held that by 3500 BCE human society had crossed the threshold
into the world’s first state society in southern Mesopotamia. This was followed
shortly thereafter by similar developments in Egypt, India, China, and the
9
Western Hemisphere. V. Gordon Childe (1950) summarized the 10 fundamental
characteristics of the world’s earliest states:
population growth
urbanization
greatly increased full-time specialization of labor beyond specialization in food production
long-distance trade in luxuries
the emergence of class-stratification with a privileged ruling class of religious, political
the development of a political organization in which membership is based on place of residen
draft labor and monumental public works projects such as the building and maintenance of tem
the use of tribute and taxation to create a central store of surplus goods to support the pr
the development of writing to facilitate the process of managing society (via the necessary
the development of scientific techniques such as arithmetic, geometry, and astronomy that ai
8.2 Gender and Politics
In societies throughout the world, political offices are held predominantly by men.
For instance, in the United States in 2013 women represent 18.3% of the members
of Congress, 12% of the governors, and about 23.4% of state legislators. But even
in societies in which men hold most positions of political power, women have a
degree of political power and influence. In patriarchal societies in which men are
economically and socially dominant, women’s power and influence is indirect, but
in more egalitarian societies it can be formally institutionalized. For instance, in
some egalitarian societies the political organization has been characterized by a
joint male–female system of authority, and in some the greatest solidarity at the
local village level has been among women. Matrifocal Societies
Women have had the greatest political power in those societies in which they
are the economic producers and control economic resources. Nancy Tanner
(1974), a specialist in the anthropology of legal processes, investigated matrifocal
societies, where the primary solidarity relations involve women. She found that
women in these societies were decision makers and at least as assertive as men,
in addition to playing the preeminent economic role. Female relatives were in
frequent contact with each other through mutual-aid groups that were a source
of power and support that was not dependent on men. In these societies, most
women generally occupied central kinship positions within their families of birth.
For instance, the role of a mother in the family was typically more important
than that of a wife.
More recent research reveals other effects of matrifocality on the family and household organization. For example, in West African matrifocal societies, marriage is
a relatively easy and even reversible process: Women may have several partners
over time, and there is often substantial support and flexibility in childrearing
(Bledsoe, 1990; Meekers, 1992). Others have emphasized generational effects,
such as the way in which daughter-based parental care underlies matrifocality
in some Caribbean societies (Quinlan, 2008). However, it is important to note
that even while women may have relatively more power in matrifocal societies
10
compared to strictly patriarchal societies, matrifocality can coexist with male
dominance (Brogger & Gilmore, 1997).
In contemporary nation-states, women have also achieved high political positions,
although not to the degree found in matrifocal societies. Worldwide, nearly 40
women have held positions as prime minister or president of their respective
countries in the first 13 years of the 21st century. Yet worldwide statistics indicate
that women continue to be numerically underrepresented in governmental offices.
The Iroquois Nineteenth century illustration by artist Friedrich Wilhelm Goedsche
depicting an Iroquois woman wearing a cape and holding a child, followed by an
Iroquois man with a musket. An Iroquois chief watches with a dagger.
Album/Florilegius/Album/SuperStock
The Iroquois are often cited as a culture in which women played important
political roles. Can you think of another culture in which women are important
to the political system? What about a culture in which women are uninvolved
politically?
The Iroquois of the North American Great Lakes region have often been cited
as a society whose culture defined women and men as equals. According to
the 19th-century anthropologist Lewis Henry Morgan (1851a), Iroquois children
belonged to their mothers’ families. Husbands were in-laws within their wives’
households and had no authority over their wives or their children. Houses
and gardens were owned by women and inherited by daughters, so women were
not economically dependent on men. The highest governmental officials were
a council of 50 chiefs, or sachems. These offices were hereditary within the
maternal families; they most often went from a man to his younger brother or
to a sister’s son, but the actual choice was made by a vote within the family.
Because only women were permitted to select the candidates for other family
members to accept or reject, Iroquois women exercised the authority of political
office in this way. Although only males were chosen to fill these offices, it was
usually possible for a family to select an infant as a sachem. Functionally, such
a choice amounted to electing the infant’s mother to the office, as she fulfilled
all the regular duties of a sachem on behalf of her son until he became mature
enough to exercise the authority of his office. The Dahomeans
According to historian Karl Polanyi (1966), women in the West African kingdom
of Dahomey (now the Republic of Benin), played even more prominent roles in
political office than did Iroquois women. In the Dahomey government, every
office held by a male had a corresponding position held by a female who was
responsible for overseeing the work of the male official. Men held their offices in
various places throughout the kingdom, while the women resided at the royal
palace, where they could report to the king. Men who served the king could
only see the king if they were accompanied by the women who maintained
oversight of their work. Even the king had such a counterpart, the Queen
Mother, whose status was higher than that of the king. The Dahomean army
had a similar organization. In the 1800s, the Dahomean army consisted of nearly
11
equal numbers of male and female warriors and officers. The elite military corps
that guarded the palace was comprised of about 2,500 celibate women warriors.
The Dahomean joint male–female system for organizing the government and the
military functioned very effectively to perpetuate the authority of the king by
insulating him from male competitors. The Kingdom of Dahomey existed from
1600 until about 1900, when it came under the control of France and many of its
traditional social forms were then transformed under colonial rule. The Lobedu
According to Eileen J. Krige and J. D. Krige (1943), the Lobedu of what is now
Mozambique and some of their neighbors vested supreme authority in queens.
The Lobedu queens had no military groups to enforce their authority. Instead,
they held their office because of their religious power to bring rain to their people
and to withhold it from their enemies. Thus, the Lobedu queen was the source
of her subjects’ welfare and general prosperity, and they regarded her as sacred.
Her life was filled primarily with religious responsibilities and ritual prohibitions
designed to perpetuate the well-being of her nation. At the end of a reign of
approximately 40 years, she was expected to commit ritual suicide—a custom
that was done away with in the 1950s.
The Lobedu queen was not permitted to marry, although she might bear children
whose “father” would be selected from among her relatives. She was expected to
maintain a “harem” of women who were bestowed upon her as “wives” by local
chiefs and nobles of her society and sometimes by foreign leaders. This custom
created a network of political alliances that ensured loyalty and good relations
between other important officials and the Lobedu queen, who became a “sonin-law” to the wife-givers. The queen sometimes created similar advantageous
political ties with Lobedu men by arranging marriages between them and women
of the harem. In implementing these customs, the Lobedu queen played roles
very similar to those that were elsewhere played by kings who entered marriages
primarily for political reasons. The Ibo
Kamene Okonjo (1976) has described a similar female–male political organization among the Ibo of Nigeria, who had two monarchs, a queen and a king.
They both exercised authority in their own areas of responsibility. The king’s
responsibilities primarily involved the lives and activities of men, while the
queen was consulted on matters that affected women. Men and women had
separate political organizations that paralleled each other in form and function.
For instance, women settled disputes among women, but made decisions that
affected both women and men. Margery Perham (1937) documented how in 1929
Ibo women exercised their political power by rioting against the British colonial government to express their dissatisfaction with policies that they deemed
harmful to women’s interests in Nigeria. Called the “the women’s war” by the
Ibo, this political action influenced about 2 million people over an area of 6,000
square miles. During and after colonialism, Ibo women played a major role in
economic and political changes within Nigeria. They were particularly integral
to agriculture, industrial production, trade, and political developments (Chuku,
2013). Gender Equality in Law
12
The family is often considered a separate entity in legal matters. For instance, in
chiefdoms, the enforcement of laws pertaining to families is under the authority
of kinship groups. In societies with state governments that monopolize the right
to use force, the law often treats the family as a special institution. Laws that
do not support the traditional customs of family life may exempt the family
from the usual rules of law. Even when family life is not exempted from the
principles of law that might impinge on it, enforcement of those laws may not
be rigorous. Thus, the legal rights of men and women may differ significantly in
matters that members of society perceive as related to the family.
The insularity of the family makes it an institution in which gender inequality
can lead to abuses that are not publicly addressed. In many societies a husband
can avoid the charge of murder of his wife by asserting that the killing was done
in defense of “family honor.” For instance, until 1989 Brazilian courts accepted
the defense of family honor in cases where it judged that the killing was in
response to a wife’s adultery. As another example, the custom of surgically
removing the clitoris of young girls, which is practiced in some countries, is a
means of perpetuating women’s subordination. However, human rights activists
from various countries increasingly view this practice as a human rights violation.
The legal systems of all contemporary nation-states arose in the context of gender
inequality, which has often been a taken-for-granted aspect of the prestate culture.
Thus, the legal interests of women (and racial minorities) tended to be ignored.
And, in many cases, gender inequality was initially written into law when states
were first formed. For instance, the male authors of the U.S. Constitution limited
full citizenship, including the right to vote, to adult white males. The federal
Constitution gave the authority to regulate voting to the states, and within
31 years, every state had explicitly denied or revoked women’s right to vote.
Women’s right to vote did not get enacted until the 19th Amendment (which
gives women the right to vote) became law on August 26, 1920, 133 years after
the Constitution was adopted. The change was not due to a sudden shift in
opinion about sexual equality; rather, it was the culmination of a long process
of change in American values.
As is common in the process of political change, there were previously both
actions to limit women’s rights as well as to enhance them. In 1867, the 14th
Amendment explicitly defined “citizens” as male. During the 1880s, female
suffrage was debated at the federal level, but was not accepted. In 1895, Utah
gave women the right to vote, and Idaho did the same in 1896. In 1910, women
in the state of Washington were granted the right to vote. Seven years later, 500
women were arrested in Washington, D.C., for participating in a silent vigil in
favor of women’s suffrage. But, in the same year, seven states granted women
either partial or full suffrage. The following year, female suffrage was given
support by the U.S. President, and two years later the 19th Amendment was
adopted.
8.3 Race and Ethnicity in Politics: The Case of Indigenous Peoples An indigenous
village sits on a mountainside overlooking a nuclear power plant.
13
iStockphoto/Thinkstock
The number of small, independent societies in the world is rapidly decreasing.
The modern world is already impacting the most isolated indigenous societies.
Political power is not always equally shared by every social group. Minority
statuses are typically not as influential in political life as are nonminorities.
Indigenous peoples are groups that were at one time politically sovereign in their
own territory, but have since become minority populations, often by conquest by a
more powerful society. Indigenous peoples are commonly the most disenfranchised
groups in modern nation-states. Indigenous Peoples
Today, about 300 to 350 million people, or nearly 6% of the world’s population,
have “indigenous” status. As we shall see, however, most indigenous people do
not continue to live their ancestral way of life. Those who do are an even smaller
minority.
Indigenous peoples live on all continents. They are found in about half of the 161
member states of the United Nations. As of the 2010 census, there are about 2.9
million Native Americans in the United States, where they represent about 1%
of the population. About 1.2 million “First Nations” people reside in Canada.
There are tens of millions of indigenous Indian people in Central and South
America. In Scandinavia there are about 70,000 Sami (formerly known as Lapps).
Maoris make up about 600,000 members of New Zealand’s population. The
Australian census indicates that there are over 500,000 Aboriginal Australians.
In Mexico, there are over 60 different indigenous groups that together comprise
almost 10% of the Mexican population. Asia is the home of the largest number
of indigenous people, but many are also found throughout Africa, India, the
Pacific Islands, and Europe.
The ancestors of today’s indigenous peoples once occupied most of the world.
Conquest and colonization changed that. Many have been dispossessed of their
traditional lands and have resettled. Those whose lands were of little use to the
national economies of the conquering states remain in their native territories,
although even these people have typically been forced into restricted areas such as
the Indian reservations of the United States. The territories of today’s indigenous
peoples, such as deserts, tundras, forests, mountains, and islands, can be termed
frontier areas, lands that are unproductive for industrialized agriculture. But
the insulation that frontier areas have provided for their inhabitants in the
past is weakening. Their natural resources are gradually attracting more and
more outsiders, both individuals and corporations, which are seeking to exploit
them for the benefit of the more urbanized economies of the states that claim
sovereignty over them. In many places around the world, indigenous peoples
are disappearing because of these outside influences. In fact, although there
are still 200 million indigenous people in the world, many indigenous cultures
have become extinct. There are three general ways in which indigenous cultures
disappear: acculturation, ethnocide, and genocide. Acculturation
When two previously distinct cultures come in contact, they both change. As
14
noted in chapter 2, this process is called acculturation. While acculturation
generally causes both cultures to change, it can change a culture so much that it
loses most of its own traditional characteristics and, in effect, becomes extinct.
Ethnocide
Sometimes the destruction of a traditional way of life is carried out by the
deliberate, systematic policies of the dominant culture. Such a process is called
ethnocide. The effect of ethnocide is that a group is denied the right to enjoy,
develop, and disseminate its own traditional culture and language. Politically
dominant societies may legally require that indigenous peoples send their children
to schools that train them in the dominant culture and language. In some cases
these are boarding schools, where the children must live for long periods of time,
far from their own families. Often the use of their native language is not only
discouraged but also forbidden and punished. Removed from the normal process
of socialization in their own native culture, they return home ill-equipped to
carry on their parents’ way of life. Missionary efforts also have contributed to
the destruction of indigenous ways of life by working for the abolition of all forms
of marriage other than monogamy and attacking traditional religious beliefs
(Ribiero, 1971; Walker, 1972). In particular, indigenous people’s conversion to
new religions often has profound effects, as religious affiliation is a key aspect of
social identity (Dow & Sandstrom, 2001). Extinction
Refugees with No Hope Khwe and !Xue tribes gather in the tent city; a tribal
representative explains the predicaments facing these tribes.
The San culture, whom you were introduced to in a previous chapter, face the threat of cultu
Do you think anthropologists could play a role in addressing the issues faces by the San? If
It is not just traditional ways of life that are changing and disappearing. In
some cases, the people themselves are becoming extinct, due in large part to
illnesses that urbanized societies introduced to indigenous peoples, and due to
governmental policies of eliminating the native peoples of regions that the more
powerful society sought to control. Such policies often resulted in genocide.
Genocide
Related to ethnocide, the destruction of a culture, is the practice of genocide,
the systematic destruction of a people. Many of the indigenous people of the
world have been and are being systematically exterminated. Military campaigns
against native peoples have been only one way in which the extinction of whole
societies has occurred. Biological warfare also has been used. In the earlier days
of U.S. history, military leaders considered distributing clothing and blankets
infected with smallpox and other diseases to some Native Americans, ostensibly
as gifts. Native people also had been given gifts of poisoned foods and had
sometimes even been hunted for sport (Bonwick, 1870; Calder, 1874; Horwood,
1969). In the past decade in many parts of Latin America, Indians have been
killed by settlers moving onto their traditional lands. This small-scale warfare
is carried out with guns, bombs, dynamite, and even rapid-fire weapons from
15
helicopters by private individuals, while national governments have turned a
blind eye to the killing. In some cases, despite the presence of indigenous people,
government agencies have declared traditional native lands to be “empty” and
therefore legitimately available for settling by nonindigenous farmers, miners,
and land speculators. For instance, in 1978, in the Department of Alta Verpaz,
Guatemala, non-Indian landowners tried to evict Kekchi Indians from lands
they had lived on for generations. When the Indians protested to the mayor
in the nearby town of Panzos, 100 were killed and 300 wounded. Within 4
years the federal government had defined all Indians as “subversives,” and a
military campaign against them had begun. In 1982 government forces massacred
302 Chuj Indians in the village of Finca San Francisco in the Department of
Huehuetenango, Guatemala. The only survivors were 20 men who were away
from the village at the time. Over a 6-month period, between 2,000 and 10,000
Indians were killed by government forces. As of 1992, over a million people have
been displaced from their homelands by these conflicts, and about 200,000 have
left the country to find refuge in other parts of Central America.
Thomas Gregor (1983) describes the impact of the immigration of nonindigenous
people into Brazil. The first European explorer arrived on the Brazilian coast in
1500. During the next 4 centuries, deaths from European diseases and intentional
killings by bounty hunters reduced the numbers of the native population. Some
were taken into slavery and others simply dispossessed of their lands. Now the
native Indian population of Brazil is only 10% of what it originally was. Skulls
of victims at the Killing Fields in Cambodia displayed in a glass-cased memorial.
iStockphoto/Thinkstock
Unfortunately, the effects of genocide are still present in the world today. Here,
skulls from the Killing Fields of Phnom Penh, Cambodia, are memorialized.
The effects of such violence have even penetrated indigenous groups that have
had little direct contact with outsiders. Gregor focuses on the Mehinaku, a
single village tribe that lives in a vast protected reservation in the Mato Grosso
of Brazil. Despite their official protection and relative isolation, contact with
Brazilians has been sufficient to undermine the security of their lives. Gregor
quotes one Mehinaku villager as saying, “Last night my dream was very bad. I
dreamed of a white man” (1983, p. 1). According to the Mehinaku, such dreams
portend illness. The symbolism is apt because, in the words of Gregor, “In the
early 1960s, almost 20% of the tribe died in a measles epidemic, and the villagers
continue to suffer from imported diseases for which they have neither natural
nor acquired immunity” (Gregor, 1983, p. 2).
The extreme lack of political influence of indigenous peoples can be illustrated by
the case of Native Americans in the United States. In 2010 there were about 2.9
million people in the United States legally defined as American Indians. Yet the
impact of minority status on indigenous Americans is clear: Native Americans
have the lowest life expectancy, at 63 years, and the highest unemployment
rates, about 50%, of any ethnic or racial group in the United States. They also
16
fall below the nation as a whole in average income, housing, and education.
Contemporary Processes of Assimilation
Originally, Native Americans were the only inhabitants of the lands now under
control of the U.S. government. Today, they find themselves in the unusual
position of being citizens both of the United States and of tribal groups that the
Supreme Court has called “domestic dependent nations” of the United States
(Cherokee Nation v. Georgia, 5 Pet. 10 [1831]). This ambiguous legal state of
affairs stems from the political history of relations between the U.S. government
and the original Native American societies that it conquered as it expanded its
borders.
From the viewpoint of Native Americans, the founders of what was to become
the United States entered North America as immigrants. Although the incoming
population was originally small, its numbers grew rapidly from continued immigration and a high birth rate, and its economic and political power increased
based on the development of industry and technology. At first, the U.S. government formally recognized the sovereignty of Native American tribes. The
Northwest Ordinance of 1787, ratified by the First Congress in 1789, declared,
“The utmost good faith shall always be observed towards Indians; their lands
and property shall never be taken from them without their consent.” (Northwest
Ordinance, 1787)
Nevertheless, as the immigrant population expanded across much of the North
American continent, its citizens entered lands occupied by Native Americans, who
found themselves overwhelmed by U.S. military power. When Native American
societies did attempt to regulate their relations with the U.S. government and
minimize the loss of their own lands and cultural identities by the negotiation
of treaties, they were treated as foreign nations. Thus Native American tribes
typically ceded some of their lands to the United States, while reserving other
lands for themselves. The U.S. government acknowledged Native American
sovereignty over their own lands, while sometimes promising economic aid and
educational rights to the tribal groups in return for the ceded lands. Native
American–U.S. relations never remained as clear-cut as the contents of these
treaties suggest, however. The expansion of the U.S. domain eventually engulfed
the various Native American territories and left Native American societies in
a more powerless position than that of other peoples who had entered into
treaties with the United States. In 1823, the Supreme Court declared that the
U.S. government had the right to govern Native Americans, saying that “the
discovery and conquest gives the conquerors sovereignty over and ownership
of the lands obtained” (Johnson v. McIntosh, 21 U.S. 542). Thus, lands that
Native Americans thought that they had reserved to themselves through treaties
became officially administered as parts of the United States itself. Tribes were
no longer to be treated as sovereign nations within their own territories but as
dependent peoples of the U.S. government. This process was formalized when
the U.S. Congress unilaterally passed legislation in 1924 that declared all Native
Americans born within the territorial limits of the United States to be U.S.
17
citizens.
Following the extension of U.S. citizenship to Native Americans, it was easy
to forget that “reservations” were U.S. lands that had been held in trust for
Native Americans who had not yet adjusted to mainstream U.S. life. U.S. treaty
obligations to residents of Native American lands came to be seen by many
non-Native Americans as “special treatment” by the federal government. There
followed a period during which tribes were encouraged to disincorporate as tribal
entities in return for settlement of claims that they had unsuccessfully pursued
for lands lost to states and to the federal government. Some tribes ceased to
exist under this policy, but others remained. Today, there are still 287 Native
American reservations in the United States, governed in part by the tribes, in
part by federal bureaus, and in part by the states in or next to which they are
located.
The uneasy mix of governing powers that controls the destinies of reservation
residents is a continuing source of conflict, both among Native Americans and
between reservation governments and non-Native American political bodies. For
instance, Crees and other tribes whose traditional lands straddled the U.S.–
Canadian border were guaranteed the right to pass unimpeded from one country
to the other by an early treaty between the United States and Canada. This right
is still in force, although U.S. border officials occasionally express annoyance
at its use by Native Americans whose vehicles are immune to the searches that
may legally be made of other vehicles that cross the border.
Many times the legal conflicts over Native American rights become major court
cases because of the economic interests at stake. For instance, treaties with
the Lumhi and several other tribes in the state of Washington have guaranteed
them free and unregulated fishing rights. These rights have been challenged by
representatives of the commercial fishing industry and by government agencies
concerned with recreational fishing, both of which have economic interests in the
maintenance of fishing quotas that those treaties prevent them from imposing
on members of the tribes. In Utah, important legal cases have been fought in
the 1980s over whether the state government has the right to tax oil companies
for oil produced by wells on the Ute Indian reservation, and over the right of the
tribe to exercise police authority over predominantly non-Native American towns
that lie within the Ute reservation. In 1989 the Ute government declared that
the federal government and the state of Utah had abrogated their contractual
obligation to build irrigation projects on the reservation in return for rights to
irrigated water that flows from the reservation—opening the way for the tribe
to withhold that water in the future.
In Idaho, a conflict continues that threatens a major source of revenue for the
Shoshone and Bannock of the Fort Hall Reservation. For years, sales of goods
such as cigarettes at untaxed prices have been an important attraction for tourist
dollars on the reservation. The Idaho state government is now asserting that this
practice is illegal, and that the tribe must collect state taxes on all such sales.
The tribal government, on the other hand, asserts that the state of Idaho has no
18
authority over tribal business practices, as reservation lands are not legally part
of the state. A similar conflict is occurring between the state of New York and
two Indian tribes, the Mohawks and the Seneca.
Sometimes the conflicting views of Native American authority to govern their
own lands have reached the point of forceful and even violent confrontations.
For instance, in 1986, the city of Scottsdale, Arizona, refused to renegotiate
the rights for non-Native Americans’ use of the Pima highway, an important
commuter road on reservation land. In response, the tribe closed the highway
to further use by non-Native Americans. Bonfires and barricades stopped the
flow of traffic until the city government capitulated. In July 1989, the New
York state police sealed off the St. Regis Reservation because Mohawk American
Indians had continued to open gambling casinos to tourists from New York,
a state that does not allow gambling. After several raids of the reservation
casinos by state police, a Mohawk group called the Sovereignty Security Force
blocked the main highway in protest against state and federal agencies that they
believed were intervening illegitimately in the internal affairs of the tribe by
attempting to prohibit gambling, a source of millions of dollars of revenue that
the tribal government had authorized. New York state troopers responded with
checkpoints of their own on roads into the reservation. For years afterwards, New
York state troopers were posted on the reservation, and the casinos remained
closed. It was not until April 6, 2000, that the federal government finally agreed
to permit the Mohawk to offer casino gambling on land held in trust for the
tribe by the Department of Interior.
The unusual legal situation of indigenous peoples in the United States involves a
complicated tangle of conflicting views about who has sovereignty over reservation
lands. Tribal, state, city, and federal governments are all involved. Sometimes
the tribes themselves disagree about who best represents their interests. Within
the federal government, conflicts sometimes arise about which government body
is responsible for determining policy on reservations. For instance, the Bureau of
Indian Affairs is usually the dominant federal party, but in some cases, policies
that influence American Indian lands adjacent to national forests or parks are set
by the National Forest Service or National Park Service. Because vast sums of
money are often at stake in these conflicts, they will likely continue. Indigenous
Peoples Today
In response to the influx of outside forces such as the logging and mining
industries, indigenous peoples throughout the world are forming organizations
to influence both national and international policies that affect their autonomy.
For instance, in 1974, the International Indian Treaty Council was formed in the
United States to bring Native American concerns before international bodies
such as the United Nations. It obtained status as a nongovernmental consultative
organization at the United Nations in 1977. In 1978 Native Americans also
formed the Indian Law Resource Center to support Indian legal rights in the
U.S. court system and through international groups such as the Council on
Human Rights. Many such organizations now exist throughout most of the
19
world. A similar international organization, the World Council of Indigenous
Peoples (WCIP), was organized in 1975. Its members are made up of delegates
who now represent over 60 million of the world’s indigenous peoples and have
observer status within the United Nations. The WCIP advocates for indigenous
peoples throughout the world. In 1982, in response to the demands of indigenous
peoples’ organizations, the UN Commission on Human Rights “established an
annual Working Group on Indigenous Populations to gather information about
the situation of indigenous peoples world-wide and make recommendations about
future international laws to protect their rights” (Burger, 1987, p. 61).
Beginning in the 1990s, numerous Latin American nations have adopted constitutional provisions recognizing, in principle, indigenous rights or at least a
multicultural framework for the continued existence of indigenous people within
their larger countries. In 2007, the General Assembly of the United Nations
adopted a “Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples,” which recognized
indigenous people’s right to self-determination within their own communities
and full rights to nationality and employment within the countries in which they
are found. These and other rights recognized in the Declaration have led to the
rise of numerous organizations involved in the political processes of advocating
on behalf of indigenous peoples around the world.
Click here to view alternate text.
8.4 Social Control: The Imposition of Order
All societies have a variety of mechanisms by which the social behavior of people is
controlled to maintain order or to re-establish order once rules have been broken.
Social efforts to create orderly behavior begin at birth and continue throughout
life. Some mechanisms for bringing about and maintaining conformity with
acceptable behavior include early teaching of accepted customs and instilling
values that motivate people to conform. Other mechanisms are punishments for
rule violations and rewards for conformity. Malinowski (1926) pointed out that
rules may be obeyed for a number of reasons: They may be followed because
violating them brings public ridicule; because playing by the rules brings more
rewarding interaction with others; because they are sacred, and supernatural
punishment will result from breaking them; or because they are matters of law
enforced by the machinery of society. They may also be self-enforcing due to
their practical utility. Socialization
The basic way we learn to fit into a social order is through our childhood
socialization or enculturation (see Chapter 2). We learn about our culture, and
we come to see the common expectations that others have about our behavior.
Those habits learned early in life set the pattern for later relationships outside
our home and community. Effective socialization can head off problems by
establishing patterns of behavior that others find acceptable.
Part of enculturation is learning to feel that some ways of behaving are better
than others. As explained in Chapter 2, values are part of the feeling subsystem
of a culture and may be defined as our attitudes or feelings about right and wrong
20
behavior. This broad category may then be divided into various types such as
moral, spiritual, or environmental values. Moral values are the attitudes or rules
that govern our relationships with our fellow human beings. Piety or spiritual
values define our relationship to the supernatural and may be reflected in the
following of specific religious rules of behavior such as the Jewish kosher laws,
rules against blasphemy, or rules about working on a sacred day. Environmental
values deal with our relationship to our physical environment so that concerns
would include pollution and the protection of endangered species. Although
morality and environmental values may be understood in purely practical terms,
such as the need for an orderly social life or an awareness that needed resources
are limited, people may accept them because they are supported by religious
teaching or simply because they are traditional. Note, for instance, that the
Judeo-Christian Ten Commandments begin with rules of piety such as “Thou
shalt have no other gods before me” but also include moral rules such as “Thou
shalt not steal.” Religion and Social Control
In fact, another major force for the maintenance of social order is religion. The
rites of passage that symbolize stages in the life of the individual as a member
of society are typically religious rituals. Myths and legends also contribute an
aura of sanctity to a way of life and increase people’s respect for the social order.
Taboos and ceremonial obligations further structure life in ways that demand
predictable conformity from members of a community. Finally, in some societies,
religious ideology directly mandates a moral life with the promise of supernatural
rewards for proper social conduct and punishments for wrong living.
The role of religion in maintaining social order is illustrated by the Hopi Indians
of the southwestern United States. As embodiments of evil among the Hopi,
witches were called Two Hearts. They loved darkness, death, and other things
that humans despise. Witches were put to death if they did not confess their evil
deeds. So the accusation of witchcraft was a powerful force in bringing people
into line with acceptable behavior.
Traditionally, the Hopi were a communally oriented society in which support of
common values was prized over individual prowess. The person who excelled
too much or too often might be suspected of being a witch. Thus, a child who
won more races than others would be advised to run more slowly in other races
so that others would not feel envy. In a society in which generosity and sharing
were valued, the accumulation of too much personal wealth might also lead to
suspicion of witchcraft. In this case, a suspect might sponsor a communal festival
in which he or she distributed goods to others, an act that eliminated the surplus
wealth and curried the favor of others simultaneously. Essentially any deviance
was an invitation for suspicious gossip, and this suspicion helped pressure people
into conforming behavior, much as the legal system in state societies is intended
to do.
In many societies, sorcery has also functioned to maintain social order. This
is possible because where people believe in the effectiveness of sorcery, the
fear of sorcery makes it possible to use threats of sorcery as punishments for
21
behavior that is socially unacceptable to a community. The practice of sorcery
by aggrieved individuals against those they feel have wronged them can also give
victims the feeling that they have some ability to strike back against wrongdoers.
For both reasons, sorcery tends to be more common in societies that do not
have other effective means for enforcing the legal rights of individuals. As noted
in Chapter 7, Beatrice Whiting (1950) showed that sorcery was most likely to
be practiced in societies that lack “individuals or groups of individuals with
delegated authority to settle disputes” (p. 90). Yet sorcery is not only employed
in dispute resolution; it is also a powerful explanation for misfortune in parts
of Africa, Haiti, and elsewhere. For example, Paul Farmer (1992) examined
how local narratives of sorcery serve as one (among several) explanation for the
HIV/AIDS epidemic. Rewards
Societies do not rely on punishments alone to maintain social order. Rewarding
acceptable behavior also encourages conformity. The praise and esteem of other
members of the community is one such reward. Promotions and salary increases
provide incentives to support corporate goals. Similarly, various forms of public
recognition reward contributions to the social group. In addition to money,
honor, and respect, people may be rewarded with greater power within the
military, police, or judicial system. Gossip and Social Pressure
As Max Gluckman pointed out, tensions between individuals or groups “are built
into the larger social order through cultural techniques of gossip and scandal”
(1963, 313). Most people value the esteem of others, so gossip and community
pressure can be a powerful force in keeping people in line. The key to the
effectiveness of gossip is that word eventually gets back to the person being
criticized. The nonconformist then has the opportunity to try to regain the
respect of others by changing the behavior that others have found unacceptable.
Direct confrontation is another form of community pressure that is sometimes
resorted to when gossip has failed. Yet anthropologists have also emphasized
that gossip is not always functional; it is also a way in which people explain and
experience their social world (White, 2000). Law Police in riot gear and holding
wooden batons walk together in a small town.
iStockphoto/Thinkstock
Modern state societies have a monopoly on the use of legal force to protect and
control their populations.
Order is also maintained through law, the cultural rules that regulate behavior
through the threat of punishment (Hoebel, 1954). Legal rules are rules of society
that are formally defined and codified into a recognized body of laws. Pospisil
(1972) has demonstrated that law in all societies has four characteristics: legal
authority, universal application, legal rights and duties, and sanction. Legal
authority is the right to compel others to obey the law by the use of force, by
the threat of force, or by punishment. All societies that have a formal system
of laws vest legal authority in one or more individuals who are charged with
the responsibility of maintaining order. They may be political specialists, heads
22
of voluntary associations, designated members of a community, or heads of
families. Universal application is the principle that the legal authority should
apply the same laws uniformly in similar situations. It is this expectation of
consistency that invests legal systems with tradition. Of course, legal authorities
may violate this principle, but the inconsistent application of law, or favoritism,
is regarded as an abuse of power in all societies. Legal rights and duties are
the formal rules that define relationships between persons by specifying what
recompense an injured person is entitled to receive and that legal authorities
are expected to follow in enforcing contracts between persons when one or both
believe their rights have been violated. Finally, sanction is the action taken by
legal authorities when the law has been violated. Sanctions may be negative or
positive. Negative sanctions are punishments and the loss of privileges or benefit
to which a person was entitled before breaking a law. They may include such
things as ridicule, ostracism, corporal punishment, or fines. Positive sanctions
are rewards for supporting the social order that is defined by law. They include
such things as monetary rewards for providing the government with information
about law violations, reduced penalties for previous violations of law based
on later “good behavior,” and the reduction of charges in return for providing
evidence against someone else who is accused of violating the law.
8.5 Conflict and Conflict Resolution
Individuals have diverse goals and are not always in agreement with one another
about their interaction with one another or about the interaction of the groups
they belong to. All societies have developed ways of attempting to minimize or
work through conflicts when they arise. Antagonistic parties may sometimes
resolve their conflict on their own, if both decide that it is no longer in their
best interest to continue their conflict or that their losses have been restored.
Peaceful conflict resolution may rely heavily on the goodwill of those involved,
whereas violent resolution may be based on the socially accepted use of force by
legal authorities. Between these two extremes are various mechanisms of social
control, such as the police and court systems in which controlled force or the
threat of the use of force is involved in conflict resolution. In this section, we will
explore a variety of social mechanisms for the resolution of conflict. Negotiation
and Adjudication
Peaceful resolution of conflict requires communication between the parties involved. Negotiation, the attempt of parties involved in a conflict to resolve
disputes by discussing their disagreements, can be carried out by the disputing
parties themselves, but it is often accomplished through mediation, which is
negotiation carried out by a go-between. Mediation is generally easier than
direct negotiation between parties, provided that the mediator is neutral. A
mediator has no authority to enforce a decision on those involved in a conflict.
Instead, as he draws on the desire of the parties involved to avoid a continuation
or escalation of their dispute, he also relies on his own prestige and his ability to
mobilize community pressure to influence the parties to settle.
Among the Nuer people of Sudan and Ethiopia, the person holding the prestigious
23
status known as leopard skin chief had no official authority over others but had
ritual responsibilities and served as a mediator between families that were in
dispute. The position of leopard skin chief was held only by a much-respected
male whose home could be a sanctuary to which a murderer might flee for safety
while a conflict was being resolved. He performed a ritual purification of the
murderer and then approached the family of the murderer to determine the
number of cattle that they were willing to pay to the family of the deceased.
Then he visited the aggrieved family to see if they would accept the offer. If
the immediate relatives pressed for retaliation, the leopard skin chief might seek
the support of more distant relatives to encourage them to accept a settlement.
Usually a settlement of about 40 cattle was accepted. Since an unrecompensed
death could lead to a feud between the families, the role of mediator was
important in maintaining social order. Nuer leopard skin chiefs were effective
because they were respected and because they were not members of either of
the lineages involved in the disputes that they mediated. Community Action
Community action is another approach to conflict resolution. In this case, the
entire community can be mobilized to respond to and resolve the conflict in
societies that lack complex kinship organizations and that are small enough to
have a vested interest in resolving the conflict among all members of the local
group. Religious Institutions
According to Black (1976), when governmental agencies of law enforcement are
weak, other means of social control are likely to be more important. As he puts
it, “Law varies inversely with other social control” (p. 6). Religion is one of
the more prominent social institutions that play a role in social control. The
most well-known examples of religious mechanisms for conflict resolution in a
legal setting are oaths and ordeals. Oaths are ritual acts of swearing innocence
on pain of punishment by deities. Where religious belief is strongly held by
people, oaths can be a powerful force in determining guilt, as the guilty may
fear supernatural retaliation too strongly to take a false oath. Ordeals are tests
of guilt or innocence in which parties in a conflict are challenged to undertake a
dangerous or painful act with the understanding that supernatural influences
will grant them success only if they are innocent. Again, the guilty are likely to
refuse such tests or fail them because their religious convictions undermine their
confidence. For instance, the Philippine Ifugao people tested the innocence of
persons accused of criminal acts by requiring them to reach quickly into a pot
of boiling water and remove pebbles from the bottom. The arm of the person
who underwent the ordeal was smeared with grease so that if he acted quickly
enough, his arm would not be burned. Those who acted out of a confidence born
of innocence were more likely to pass this test than were those whose guilt made
them hesitate. Similar tests were reported in medieval Europe and for the Tanala
of Madagascar, and in these cases, the arms of the accused were unprotected
from the boiling water by grease. However, a period of several days was allowed
to pass before the arms were examined; this lapse of time presumably favored the
innocent who acted with less hesitation than the guilty, as those with less severe
scalds were more likely to have healed by then. Courts A female attorney speaks
24
with a judge as her client stands beside her wearing an orange jail uniform.
iStockphoto/Thinkstock
State societies often utilize a formal court system to solve disputes between
individuals or between the state and individuals.
In societies that have economies that can support judicial specialists, adjudication
may become more common than mediation. Adjudication involves the use of a
third party, such as a judge or arbitrator, who is deemed neutral and who has
authority to make a final decision that is binding on both parties to a conflict.
In societies that have the resources to do so, a formal system of courts carries
out the responsibility of adjudication of the legal issues involved in conflicts
and in the violation of laws. A court is a formalized institution that asserts
authority over parties in a dispute and over persons accused of violating the
law. A court has power to decide cases and impose sanctions. Courts are part of
political systems in which governing authorities have the right to exercise control
over persons outside their own kinship group, so true courts are found only in
chiefdoms and states, societies with centralized political officials. Compensation
Whether dealt with by negotiation, mediation, community action, religious
institutions, or courts, an injury cannot always be made right. One alternative in
such cases is that compensation may be accepted because the payment symbolizes
an admission of responsibility by the wrongdoer and allows the injured party to
withdraw from the conflict honorably. For instance, the concept of compensation
has been applied in many societies, even for major acts such as murder. It
was called wer-gild, or “man-payment,” in Anglo-Saxon England before the
Norman invasion of 1066. According to Evans-Pritchard (1940), the same idea
was practiced by the Nuer of the Sudan in recent times. Among the Nuer, the
payment took the form of cattle given by the family of the murderer to the
surviving relatives. Civil actions in court in which parties sue for compensation
for injuries play a similar role in contemporary state societies. Crime
In addition to interpersonal and group conflicts, there is also a form of conflict
between government and individuals or groups. Such conflicts are those that
involve the violation of laws (formal rules set by government itself). Laws are
intended to prevent the violation of those rights of individuals, groups, and
the government itself that are recognized as such by government. Laws define
the realm of crime, which is harming a person or government or of personal or
governmental property.
Societies differ in the frequency and likelihood of various kinds of crime and in
how they deal with it. People who live in small groups have little opportunity
to harm another member of the group while remaining anonymous and profiting
by the act. In large societies, crime is more feasible because the perpetrator
can remain anonymous. The motivation, however, to violate others’ rights
for personal gain is certainly not accepted by everyone in such societies, so
population growth alone cannot be the sole cause of greater rates of crime in
such societies. Rather, it appears that the individuals most likely to resort to
25
crime in large societies are those who are unable to fulfill the values that a
society’s culture encourages. Two related factors that differentiate people in this
respect are social class and income.
Crime varies in frequency from extremely low levels in societies such as the !Kung
San foragers of southern Africa (Lee, 1979, 1984) and the Semai horticulturalists
of the Malay Peninsula (Dentan, 1968), where crime has been described as
almost nonexistent, to societies such as the Yąnomamö (Chagnon, 1983), in
which about 23% of the men of each generation die violently. Nevertheless,
people in all societies have some concept of crime and consider some harmful
acts to be legitimately punishable. Theft, assault against members of one’s own
community, and murder are probably regarded as crimes everywhere.
Although theft is typically regarded as wrong, the definition of theft differs
from culture to culture. In many societies, personal property may be freely
borrowed without asking unless the owner expressly indicates that an item
is not to be taken. This is particularly likely in societies in which generous
sharing of resources is common. For instance, Goldman (1972) described casual
attitude regarding property rights among the Cubeo, a horticultural tribe of the
Colombian Amazon Basin:
Sisters exchange ornaments and trinkets and men borrow freely from one another
with or without permission. They seem to be most free with objects of economic
utility, such as a canoe, weapons, implements, and somewhat more possessive
with objects of personal adornment. (pp. 75–76)
In this context of rather nonchalant attitudes about property rights and borrowing, Goldman recounted an interesting story about borrowing among the
Cubeo:
A visitor from an upriver sib [kinship group] rose to leave, after having spent
most of the day in amiable talk, and in a most casual voice said, “I will take my
spear with me.” A young man then went to his quarters and fetched the spear,
which the visitor took as he departed. The young man explained that he had
been at this man’s house during a drinking party. He saw the spear and admired
it and took it home without saying anything about it. Theft to the Cubeo is not
a matter of purloining an object. It is entirely a matter of attitude. (p. 76)
Societies also differ in the likelihood of theft. For instance, in foraging bands of 50
or 60 people, it would be difficult if not impossible to steal the personal property
of another and remain undetected. Furthermore, it is generally advantageous to
let others borrow one’s tools rather freely, as the fruits of everyone’s labor will
benefit the entire group. Thus, the very motive for theft can be undermined by
cultural practices such as the custom, in many hunting and gathering societies,
of leaving implements outside the hut when it is permissible for others to use
them.
Homicide is universally regarded as a criminal act, but cultures vary in what they
define as homicide. There is probably no society in which the taking of some
26
human life by someone is considered under all circumstances to be murder. For
instance, killing is an accepted part of warfare, and killing to protect someone from
being killed is typically accepted in most societies. Nevertheless, the intentional
taking of another life without justification, however justification happens to be
defined, is considered murder practically everywhere. An interesting exception
to this general rule was reported by Jenness (1922), who asserted that among
Copper Eskimo men, the likelihood of their killing at least one person was so
high that only repeated offenses were considered to be murder. This was an
important distinction because murder was a capital offense, and taking the life of
everyone who had killed just once would have been impossible. Legal Response
to Crime
In simply organized societies, the enforcement of legal rights is largely left
in the hands of individuals and their families. Where the magnitude of the
crime threatens to disrupt the community permanently, corporal punishment,
confiscation of property, ostracism, or even death are possible sanctions. Bands
and tribes are likely to respond to wrongdoing in ways that are designed to
return the group to the balance it had before a law was broken, a concept known
as restitution.
While restitution can involve benefits given to the wronged party, in many
societies, the rebalancing of the conflicting groups was achieved by exacting a
penalty against the wrongdoers to eliminate the advantage their wrongful acts
had brought them. For instance, Beattie (1964) reported that the Berbers of
North Africa expected exact equivalence in revenge for a death: “So if a man
in one group kills a woman in another, the object of the injured group will be
not to kill the murderer, but to kill a woman on their opponent’s side” (p. 175).
This is the same principle of an eye for an eye that was set forth in Hammurabi’s
famous code.
Law enforcement in complex societies tends toward an emphasis on punishment
of the criminal. This is probably because crime in societies with full-time
law enforcement officials tends to be viewed as a threat to the legitimacy of
the government’s authority. The reaction of the enforcement system in such
societies is to eliminate, imprison, or otherwise punish the wrongdoer; punishment
typically becomes more important than seeing that restitution is made to the
victim. In recent times in the United States and other industrialized countries,
efforts have been made to pass various victim compensation laws, but the
predominant emphasis in industrialized societies remains punishment; it is still
regarded as the victim’s obligation to seek recompense through civil suits. Violent
Conflict
Conflicts cannot always be ended peacefully. There are a variety of forceful
ways in which people attempt to regulate their relationships with one another,
including retribution, feuds, raids, and warfare. Retribution
In many societies that have no centralized governmental authority for the
enforcement of law, the responsibility for the punishment of wrongs is the
27
legitimate authority of the person whose rights have been violated. In such
cases, law enforcement is synonymous with retribution, the personal use of force
to redress wrongs. Retribution as a legal principle is not the same as anarchy
because it is legitimate in societies that condone it only when other members
of the community recognize that the aggrieved party has a valid complaint
that deserves redressing. Crime, anarchy, and other uses of power that are not
condoned by the larger community will be seen as illegitimate and punishable.
Feuds
Armed conflicts between two kinship groups that are initiated by one of the
groups to avenge a wrong are called feuds. The most common cause of feuds is
the murder of a member of one of the groups. Feuds may occur between kinship
groups that reside in the same community, as well as between neighboring groups
from different communities. They are most common in societies in which bodies
of related males, called fraternal groups, work together and feel obliged to protect
one another’s common interests. Raids
Organized violence by one group against another to achieve an economic benefit
is called a raid. Raiding is generally a more recurrent and ongoing process than
feuding, as the latter is stimulated by a specific grievance and may eventually be
settled. The economic advantage gained in raiding is likely to be a continuing
motivation for this organized violence. Its goal is not to eliminate or even
subjugate the enemy permanently but rather to accomplish a limited objective
such as the acquisition of food, cattle, or other valued goods. Where raiding
is common, the enemy is likely to be treated as a resource that must be left
available for future exploitation. War Tribal men in New Guinea sit behind a
shield topped with decorated skulls.
John Scofield/National Geographic Stock
In addition to its use in solving disputes, warfare is used for revenge and serves
as an apparatus for male status. Trophy taking is just one of many status
mechanisms associated with warfare.
The most extensive form of organized violence is war, armed combat between
political communities. The nature of war differs according to the complexity
of the societies involved. For instance, warfare is least common in those band
societies in which individual, communal, or plant-focused foraging is the basis
of subsistence. In fact, some have argued that warfare is generally nonexistent
among foraging societies that have low resource density and low population
density due, in part, to the social emphasis on cooperation. Moreover, among
foraging groups, when the frequency of exogamous marriages (marriages between
groups, rather than within groups) exceeds 60%, there tends to be less warfare
(Kelly, 2000). Warfare is, however, more common in bands with animal-focused
foraging. And it is most common in food-producing societies.
Otterbein (1970) examined cross-cultural data of 50 societies and found that
those with more centrally organized political institutions had more complex
military organizations, more effective weapons and tactics, and greater mortality
28
in their engagements than societies with little or no political centralization. In
general, warfare was less complex among bands and tribes than among chiefdoms
and states. For instance, the former societies lacked professional soldiers, which
were typical in the latter. The tactic of surprise was more characteristic of
simpler societies, while warfare was more formally arranged and conducted in
complex societies.
Otterbein found that the purposes of warfare also differed for the two groups.
In bands and tribes, those fighting in wars were individually motivated to
participate because of personal grudges. So battles tended to consist of many
simultaneous fights between individuals with little group strategy. Defense of
one’s own village and the benefits of plunder were the motives for war in bands
and tribal societies. Of course, more complex societies fought wars for these
reasons as well, but they were also influenced by motives less characteristic of
warfare in bands and tribes. Enhancing one’s own and one’s family’s prestige
was an especially common motivation in chiefdoms, in which competition for
prestige is a prominent characteristic. On the other hand, prestige is a less
common motive in states where social ranking was more stable and was based
on a person’s membership in a particular social class. While warfare carried out
to achieve economic and political control over other communities was a motive
found in some of the more complex chiefdoms, it was especially characteristic
of states. In addition to these points noted by Otterbein, societies that have a
form of centralized political organization can also compel individuals through
draft to participate in warfare whether they desire to or not. War and Gender
Otterbein (1970) also distinguishes between internal warfare, in which the combat
is between neighboring political communities that share the same culture, and
external warfare, in which the conflict is between political communities with
different cultures. Internal warfare is especially common among foraging bands
and horticultural tribes, while external warfare is more commonly practiced by
more complex chiefdoms and state societies. According to Divale and Harris
(1976), internal warfare is particularly associated with the systematic subordination of women. Harris (1974) has summarized the impact of this form of warfare
on male and female roles:
Male supremacy is a case of “positive feedback,” or what has been called
“deviation amplification”—the kind of process that leads to the head-splitting
squeaks of public-address systems that pick up and then reamplify their own
signals. The fiercer the males, the greater the amount of warfare, the more such
males are needed. Also, the fiercer the males, the more sexually aggressive they
become, the more exploited are the females, and the higher the incidence of
polygyny—control over several wives by one man. Polygyny in turn intensifies
the shortage of women, raises the level of frustration among the junior males,
and increases the motivation for going to war. The amplification builds to an
excruciating climax; females are held in contempt and killed in infancy, making
it necessary for men to go to war to capture wives in order to rear additional
numbers of aggressive males. (p. 87)
29
As female children are often unwanted in these societies because they lack social
power but still need to be fed, Divale and Harris contend that female infanticide,
the killing of female offspring, has been the major means of population control
in most societies throughout human history. Divale (1972) studied foraging and
horticultural societies that practiced warfare and found that the ratio of boys to
girls aged 14 and under was 128 to 100. Throughout the world about 105 boys
are born for every 100 girls; the extra 23 boys per 100 girls in Divale’s sample
indicates a higher death rate among girls in these societies.
The female subordination that occurs with internal warfare does not accompany
external warfare, in which men are absent from home for prolonged periods
while fighting with distant enemies. Women in these societies are likely to be
ranked high, as they are the ones who make the day-to-day economic and internal
political decisions of the village while the men are away. In such societies, the
gardens and houses are often the property of women, female infanticide and
polygyny are likely to be uncommon, and inheritance is usually through the
line of female ancestry. The power of men over their wives is minimized by
their lack of ownership over their wives’ home and gardens as well as their
lack of authority over their wives’ children, who are members of their mothers’
families, not their fathers’. The male head of the household is not a woman’s
husband but her brother, who belongs to her own family. In these societies
women often have great influence on the political decisions that lead to war and
that influence its conduct. Their economic roles are also an important source
of power. For instance, Iroquois women in the late 18th century were able to
control men’s wartime activities by withholding the food used to provision long
wartime expeditions. Causes of War
There are diverse theories about the cause of warfare. Ember (1982) examined
cross-cultural data and found that scarcity of resources such as food and fuel was
one predictor of the frequency of warfare. Vayda (1976) pointed out that slashand-burn horticulture stimulates internal warfare in many societies because taking
land that has already been worked by neighboring groups may be easier than
clearing new land and preparing it for cultivation. Warfare allows horticulturalists
to expand geographically when population growth overtaxes local abilities to
produce enough food. Divale and Harris (1976) suggested that internal warfare
is part of a system that helps to limit population growth because warfare fosters
male dominance, subjugation of women, a preference for male offspring, and
therefore high rates of female infanticide, which has a major impact on population
growth.
Naroll (1966) examined possible causes of the frequency of warfare. He determined that a high degree of military sophistication was not associated with
lower frequencies of war. In fact, societies with a sophisticated military force
were not only more aggressive than militarily less organized societies, but they
were more likely to be attacked as well. Beyond food scarcity, population issues,
and military capacities, there are other social explanations for the frequency of
warfare, such as forms of marriage, competition over resources, and settlement
30
patterns (Kelly, 2000). Rebellion and Revolution
The most dramatic forms of internal conflict are rebellion and revolution. Rebellion is an organized and violent opposition to the legitimacy of a society’s
current governing body. It is most likely to occur when a significant number
of those who are subject to the government’s authority feel themselves to be
disenfranchised or inadequately represented by their leaders. Rebellion seeks to
influence the policies of government and how they are carried out, but it does
not attempt to change the nature of the governmental system itself. Revolution
is the organized use of force to alter the very form of government. It is fostered
by the same conditions that lead to rebellion, but it is likely to occur when those
involved view the very system of government as the source of its illegitimate
policy and practices. Both rebellion and revolution have much in common with
warfare, as all three represent conflicts, often violent ones, between at least two
groups, each of which asserts the legitimacy of its own right to use force for its
own political ends. Arab Spring and Social Media
Politics are never limited to state-level organization and practices; rather, laypeople are key to political participation and transformation. This becomes evident
during times of turmoil, when people rise up against their governments. Such
uprisings increasingly employ social media (such as Facebook and Twitter, but
also television and video) to rally support for their political causes and broadcast
their grievances to fellow citizens and to the world.
For example, the media played an integral role in the “Arab Spring”: the wave of
protests that swept the Arab world—Tunisia, Egypt, Libya, Iraq, and Lebanon,
among others—beginning in December 2010. The movement was spurred by
popular dissatisfaction with local governments, political corruption, and human
rights violations, as well as economic issues (such as rising unemployment and
poverty). In some cases, the protests resulted in rulers being forced to resign; in
other cases, they resulted in civil wars.
Along with strikes, mass demonstrations, and rallies, the movement is notable
for its effective use of social media to organize protest efforts, create feelings of
community, and communicate local concerns. In fact, there is an ongoing debate
about whether social media was the cause of the movement or simply a tool used
in it. Some believe that social media facilitated the spread of democratic ideas
from abroad, spurring popular discontent with government officials (Howard, et
al. 2011). Regardless of whether it was the cause or a tool, social media was
prominent within the movement. For example, 9 out of 10 Egyptians reported
using Facebook to organize protests and raise social awareness (Huang, 2011).
Further, the number of Facebook users...
Purchase answer to see full
attachment