POLS 4133 International Political Economy
Debate Paper Guidelines
Spring 2017
The goal of the debate papers is to evaluate and critique major policy approaches to IPE
topics. Therefore, you will evaluate the information on a contentious issue and then
convince the audience that your opinion is valid and defensible. Your job is to take one
side of the argument and then persuade your audience that the evidence validates your
claims and refutes any counterclaims.
Guidelines for the papers are as follows:
1. Students may not select alternate topics. Specific questions for each debate will be
given.
2. Each paper will be a maximum of three pages of text in length, not including a cover
page or a bibliography. Your text should be no more than 3 pages, double-spaced, with
one-inch margins, and 12-point Times New Roman font.
Your paper will be organized to include:
• An introductory paragraph that describes your thesis/position statement on the
topic. Your position should be clear and based on facts rather than belief or
opinion.
• At least two to three paragraphs giving relevant evidence to support your position.
Each paragraph should focus on only one point of evidence. Paragraphs are
typically organized from weakest point to strongest point.
• At least one paragraph that provides a refutation of the most significant
counterargument to your position. Be sure to say why the counterclaim is not
supported based on facts or false logic in the claim itself.
• At least one paragraph concluding your paper.
To help you organize the information in your papers, you might wish to consider the
following questions as you read the sources and gather your evidence.
• What is the author’s main argument? What research question is the author trying
to answer? What are the assumptions, explicit and implicit, upon which the
author’s argument is based?
• What are the strengths and weaknesses of the author’s analysis? Can you think of
an alternative explanation for the author’s evidence?
• Do you agree or disagree with the author? How would you approach a similar
puzzle? What questions still need to be addressed?
• What advice would you give to policy makers based on this reading?
3. Students must use the readings provided to form the basis of their evidence. Students
may supplement these readings with additional evidence taken from credible sources or
1
peer reviewed academic research. news Students must cite all sources with in-text
citations and include full citations in a bibliography.
4. Students are expected to submit papers that have been carefully edited and are free
from common mistakes in spelling, grammar, and formatting.
In grading your papers, I will be looking for evidence that you (a) clearly explain
your thesis, (b) provide strong support of your thesis using evidence from the course, (c)
provide a discussion of at least one counterclaim, (d) use concepts and themes from our
course, and (e) follow writing conventions. You will also receive credit for (f) relevant
and engaging class participation on the day of the debate.
NOTE: Failure to follow these guidelines will result in a reduction of points
awarded.
2
Muhammad Yunus, founder and managing director of the Grameen Bank, was awarded the Nobel Peace Prize in 2006
for developing the concept of microcredit as “an important instrument in the struggle against poverty.” He is the author, with
Karl Weber, of Creating a World Without Poverty (Public Affairs, 2008).
Economic Security for a World in Crisis
Muhammad Yunus
Capitalism is in serious crisis. Even so, no
one is calling for it to be abandoned in favor
of some other system, such as socialism,
because everybody is convinced that, with
all its faults, capitalism is still the best
economic system known to humanity. As
every student knows, Adam Smith provided
the conceptual framework of capitalism. It
has been improved and elaborated throughout its long history, and though the world
has changed enormously, the fundamentals
described by Smith have remained largely
intact.
The need for reviewing the basic structure of capitalism has seemed appropriate on
many occasions, but never so clearly as it is
today. Indeed, in light of the current global
economic crisis, there is strong support for a
major overhaul of the system. In my view,
one major change in the theoretical framework of capitalism is necessary—a change
that will allow individuals to express themselves in multi-dimensional ways and address the problems left unsolved or even
intensified by the existing conceptual framework. And although my proposal may be
viewed as a significant change in the structure of capitalism, it is actually very consistent with what Adam Smith elaborated so
brilliantly in his Theory of Moral Sentiments
in 1759. Some 250 years later, however,
© 2009 World Policy Institute
some of Smith’s lessons still have not been
learned adequately.
Until the current economic crisis, observers around the world shared a remarkably optimistic view of the future of civilization. In the early years of the twentyfirst century, we were living in a time of
unparalleled prosperity, fueled in part by
revolutions in knowledge, science, and technology. This prosperity had dramatically
improved the lives of many; yet billions of
people still suffered from poverty, hunger,
and disease. In the developed world, a handful of economists and social scientists had
been clamoring to draw attention to their
plight. Many people, however, took a complacent view, assuming that the spread of
free markets would bring eventual prosperity even to the world’s poorest peoples.
The twenty-first century began with
high hopes and idealistic dreams, encapsulated in the United Nations initiative
known as the Millennium Development
Goals. These eight goals, to which the international community pledged its support, included several economic objectives (such as
eradicating extreme poverty and developing
a global partnership for development) as
well as other humanitarian objectives (such
as reducing gender inequality and achieving
universal primary education). Taken togeth5
er, these goals would carry us a long way toward the broader objective of greatly reducing the gulf between the rich nations of the
global North and the poor nations of the
global South. Many of us were convinced
that the coming decades would bring unprecedented wealth and prosperity, not just
for a few, but for all people on this planet.
Now the mood of optimism has
changed. Several major crises that few people foresaw—the financial crisis, the everworsening environmental crisis, and crises
over food and oil prices—have converged to
bring even greater misery and frustration to
the world’s bottom three billion people.
And these crises have also driven many in
the developed world to question the solidity
of the foundations on which they had assumed their future security and prosperity
were being built.
A Rude Awakening
The crises we face in food, energy, and the
environment have a host of immediate economic and physical causes. But they all have
one thing in common. They all reflect the
inadequacy of the current economic system.
In each case, we confront social problems
that cannot be solved solely by the free market as it is traditionally understood.
On top of all this has come the biggest
crisis of all. In the past few months, we’ve
witnessed perhaps the greatest evaporation
of wealth in history. The crushing collapse
of large sectors of the global financial system, first in the United States, then in other
nations of the developed world has doomed
giant financial institutions, bankrupted major manufacturing firms, and nearly shuttered entire domestic industries, now kept
alive only with unprecedented government
bailout packages. Many reasons have been
suggested for this historic economic collapse: excessive greed in the marketplace,
the transformation of investment markets
into gambling casinos, and the failure of
6
regulatory institutions. But one thing is
clear. The financial system has broken down
because of a fundamental distortion of its
basic purpose.
Credit markets were originally created
to serve human needs—to provide business
people with capital to start or expand companies. In return for these services, bankers
and other lenders earned a reasonable profit.
Everyone benefited. In recent years, however, the credit markets have been distorted
by a relative handful of individuals and
companies with a different goal in mind—
to earn unrealistically high rates of return
through clever feats of financial engineering.
They repackaged mortgages and other loans
into sophisticated instruments whose risk
levels and other characteristics were hidden
or disguised. Then they sold and resold
these instruments, earning a slice of profit
on every transaction. All the while, investors
eagerly bid up the prices, scrambling for
unsustainable growth and gambling that the
underlying weakness of the system would
never come to light.
In time, the inevitable happened. The
house of cards came tumbling down. Because of the degree of globalization in financial markets, this economic tsunami has
spread across the world. Stock markets
around the globe have suffered losses in
the billions, even trillions of dollars. But
the rich will not be the most affected by
this financial crisis; rather it will be the
bottom three billion people on this planet
who will truly suffer, despite the fact that
they are not responsible in any way for creating this disaster. While the rich will continue to enjoy a privileged lifestyle, the
poor will face job and income losses that,
for many, will make the difference between
life and death.
The impact is already beginning to be
felt. As levels of global trade decline, exports from the developing nations are down.
Foreign direct investment in development
WORLD POLICY JOURNAL • SUMMER 2009
by the wealthy nations is expected to drop
by 20 percent this year. Funds for lending
have dried up, as have aid flows and remittances from citizens working abroad.
We have only seen the beginning of
these crises. We are in for a long and painful
period ahead. The combined effects of the
financial, food, energy, and environmental
crises will continue to unfold in the coming
months and years, affecting the security of
the bottom three billion with particular
force. One example: the World Bank has estimated that unless the financial crisis is
quickly resolved, an additional 1.4 million
to 2.8 million children in the developing
world will die of malnutrition between
2010 and 2015.
The troubles of the world’s poorest will
have an impact on those in developed nations, too. Social unrest, border clashes over
scarce resources, increasing instances of state
failure, and vast migrations by populations
desperate for relief from poverty and environmental disaster will create political and
military hot spots around the globe that
will threaten world peace and strain the
budgets of established and emerging powers
struggling to cope with these challenges.
Economic Security for a World in Crisis
Over the past several months, world
leaders have been particularly focused on
financial emergencies. This is quite understandable. But it should not be seen as a
problem of high finance only. This narrow
view of the financial crisis is likely to intensify our global social and political problems.
The human aspect of the financial crisis
must be integrated into a holistic solution
to the problems that we all face.
So far, governments have kept themselves busy coming up with super-sized
bail-out packages for the institutions responsible for creating the financial crisis, yet
little is being done to bail out the most vulnerable victims. Still, the decision in early
April by the leaders of the G-20 Summit to
“recapitalize” the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) to the tune of $750 billion is a
welcome start. These funds will enable the
IMF to help stabilize threatened banks in
troubled regions of the world, such as eastern Europe. In a global crisis like the one
we face today, relief to any region helps the
whole world by reducing the chance that
economic collapse will continue to spread.
Yet, in the face of all this dire news, it
is possible that this mega-crisis could be a
7
mega-opportunity—to redesign our existing
economic and financial systems so that they
can become the foundations for lasting
global security.
Capitalism: a Half-Built Structure
Even if we can overcome the immediate
crises we face, we will still be left with fundamental questions about the effectiveness
of capitalism in tackling such unresolved
problems as persistent poverty, lack of access
to health care and education, and epidemic
diseases. In my view, the theoretical framework of capitalism that is widely accepted
today is a half-built structure—one that
prevents Adam Smith’s “invisible hand”
from operating as he believed it should,
transforming the pursuit of individual gain
into general social benefit through the
workings of the marketplace.
In a sense, we have chosen to disregard
half of Smith’s message. His landmark book,
The Wealth of Nations, has drawn all the attention, while his equally important Theory
of Moral Sentiments has been largely ignored.
The present theory of capitalism holds
that the marketplace is uniquely for those
who are interested in profit only. This interpretation treats people as one-dimensional
beings; but people are multi-dimensional, as
Adam Smith saw so clearly two and a half
centuries back. While we have a selfish dimension, we also have a selfless dimension.
The prevailing theory of capitalism, and the
marketplace that has grown up around the
theory, makes no room for the selfless dimension of people. If the altruistic motivation that exists in people could be brought
into the business world, there would be few
problems we could not solve.
Smith took the view that people are
born with a moral sense, just as they have
inborn ideas of beauty or harmony. Our conscience tells us what is right and wrong.
That conscience is something innate, not
something given to us by lawmakers or by
8
rational analysis. And to bolster it we also
have a natural tendency to care about the
well-being of our fellow men and women,
an apparently universal feeling which Smith
calls “sympathy.” Between them, these natural senses of conscience and sympathy ensure
that human beings can and do live together
in orderly, beneficial social organizations.
With these ideas in mind, we can see
that Smith’s Wealth of Nations has generally
been misinterpreted. His thesis in that book
is generally summarized as an argument
that all will be well if people are allowed to
follow “self-interest,” which has been equated with selfishness and profit maximization.
But with human beings as they are—driven
by conscience and sympathy as well as the
desire for profit—“self-interest” includes
both profit maximization and social contribution. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, which
attached great importance to justice and
other moral virtues, is thus an important
corrective to the widespread but simplistic
understanding of Smith’s intentions in
The Wealth of Nations.
However, the present structure of economic theory does not allow this latter dimension to play out in the marketplace. In
the absence of such an opportunity, people
have tended to express their selflessness
through contributions to charities. Charitable efforts have always played a role in our
society and economy. They are noble, and
they are needed. But business has a greater
capacity than charity to innovate, to expand,
and to reach more and more people through
the power of the free market. If the efficiency, competitiveness, and dynamism of the
business world can be harnessed to deal with
specific social problems, the entire world
will be a much better place. Imagine what
we could achieve if talented entrepreneurs
and business executives around the globe
devoted themselves to goals such as ending
malnutrition, providing shelter for the
homeless, and eradicating disease.
WORLD POLICY JOURNAL • SUMMER 2009
With this in mind, I have proposed a
new type of business that would operate in
the same market along with existing profitmaximizing enterprises. I call these new
entities “social businesses,” because they
exist for the collective benefit of others.
Missing Element: Social Business
A social business is one whose purpose is to
address and solve social problems, not to
make money for its investors. It is a nonloss, non-dividend-paying company. The investor can recoup his investment capital, but beyond that, no profit is to
be taken out as dividends by the investors.
These profits remain
with the company and
are used to expand its outreach, to improve
the quality of the product or service it provides, and to design methods to bring down
the cost of the product or service. In effect,
social business will represent a third economic sector alongside the free market and
government.
It is important to distinguish the concept of social business from the well-known
idea of “socially-responsible business.” The
latter refers to traditional for-profit companies that choose to modify their business activities so as to promote social goals, or, at
least, to minimize the social harms they
cause. Socially-responsible businesses may
use environmentally-friendly methods, provide generous benefits to employees and
their families, and donate a portion of their
profits to worthwhile causes. Today, many
companies try to promote themselves as being socially responsible, and specialized investment funds exist to channel money toward such companies and away from others
that are polluters, abusers of their employees, or exploiters of the poor.
The difference between a social business,
“
Economic Security for a World in Crisis
as I define it, and a socially-responsible
business is that, for the latter, profit-maximization remains the primary goal. When
the goal of increasing profit is seen as conflicting with the goal of helping society, the
managers of the socially-responsible business
must favor the pursuit of profit. During bad
economic times, a socially-responsible business is likely to cut back on its charitable
giving and cut corners on its other social
commitments. A social business cannot
Business has a greater ability than
charity to innovate, expand, and
reach people through the power
of the free market.
”
make such a choice. Its whole reason for existing is to promote social benefits. Therefore, there can be no conflict between this
goal and the goal of earning a profit, which
the social business doesn’t recognize at all.
The concept of social business crystallized in my mind through my experience
with Grameen—a family of companies, 25
in all, founded by Grameen Bank over the
past 27 years in an attempt to address different problems faced by the poor in
Bangladesh. These companies vary widely in
their goals and business models. Grameen
Shakti, for example, produces and sells lowcost, renewable energy systems, including
solar panels and bio-gas converters that turn
otherwise valueless farm wastes into cooking
fuel. Grameen Health Care runs health clinics and provides affordable health insurance
to rural families. Grameen Fisheries and
Livestock operates fish farms and provides
vaccination and veterinary services to help
small farmers in Bangladesh improve profitability. Grameen Bank itself is a social
business. Owned by poor people, mostly
women, who are its depositors and borrow9
ers, it pays part of its profits back to the
owners in the form of dividends, and invests
the rest in expanding services to more villages and families throughout the country.
All of the revenues that flow through
Grameen Bank go to help the poor in one
way or another. In each case, the companies
address a specific social need. We designed
these businesses to be both self-sustaining
and expanding, but only to ensure that the
products or services they provide can reach
more and more of the poor, on an ongoing
basis. Any surpluses generated by these
companies are reinvested to expand operations, rather than enrich investors. This is
the model of a social business.
The concept of social business got
international attention when Grameen
Bank launched a joint venture with Danone,
a multinational company headquartered in
France. In February 2006, Grameen teamed
up with Danone to bring nutritious fortified
yogurt to the undernourished children of
rural Bangladesh. The aim of this social
business was to fill a nutritional gap in the
diet of these children. Today, we sell the yogurt to poor families at an affordable price,
charging just enough to make the company
self-sustaining. In the process, we stimulate
the local economy, since the yogurt is distributed door to door by a small army of village women who earn a commission on each
cup of yogurt they sell. Furthermore, all the
milk and other ingredients in the yogurt are
purchased from local suppliers, such as
small dairy farmers in the vicinity of the
factory. Beyond the return of the original investment capital, by agreement, neither
Grameen nor Danone will ever make any
money from this venture. We have one yogurt plant already operating in Bangladesh
and, in time, hope to have 50 such plants
throughout the country.
We also have built an eye-care hospital
that operates along social business principles
and a joint venture with Veolia of France to
10
deliver safe drinking water to rural villages.
This partnership is building a small watertreatment plant to bring clean water to
50,000 villagers in an area of Bangladesh
where the existing water supply is highly
contaminated with arsenic. We will sell the
water at an affordable price solely to make
the company sustainable, but no financial
gain will come to Grameen or Veolia. The
success of these enterprises has encouraged
other companies to come forward and partner with us to set up new social businesses.
Teach a Man to Fish
Some people are still skeptical, however,
when I describe the concept of social business. “Who will create these businesses?”
they ask. “Who will run these businesses?
And, more important, why would anyone
devote time, energy, and money to projects
with no hope of personal gain?”
To begin with, there is no dearth of philanthropists in the world and no dearth of
donor countries giving grants. People give
away billions of dollars every year, as do
donor countries. But imagine if, instead of
those billions of dollars going to supply
one-time aid, they could be used by social
businesses to help people. The money would
then be recycled again and again, and the
social impact could be that much more
powerful. In the same manner, money allocated by companies to corporate social responsibility projects could easily go into developing social businesses. Each company
could create its own range of social businesses or pool donations from many sources in
Social Business Funds (SBF), comparable to
private equity pools that operate in the forprofit world. There’s a danger here, of
course, given the lessons we’ve learned from
the global financial crisis. But since investment in an SBF would be driven by social
objectives rather than profit, it is reasonable
to assume that rampant market ills would
be less likely to affect them.
WORLD POLICY JOURNAL • SUMMER 2009
©Karl Weber
Waiting for a Grameen shareholders’ meeting.
The opportunities for launching social
businesses are limitless. Even profit-maximizing companies can be social businesses
when owned by the poor. This constitutes a
second type of social business. Grameen
Bank falls under this category of social business. It is owned by its poor borrowers. The
borrowers buy Grameen Bank shares with
their own money, and these shares cannot be
transferred to non-borrowers. A committed
professional team does the day-to-day running of the bank. Every year, dividend
checks are sent to the borrowers, representing their share of the bank’s profits.
What I would like to propose here is
that bilateral and multilateral donors support economic development by creating social businesses of this type. When a donor
wants to give a loan or a grant to, say, build
a bridge in a recipient country, it could create instead a bridge-building company
owned by the local poor. A committed management company would be given the reEconomic Security for a World in Crisis
sponsibility of running the company. Following the established model, part of the
profits earned would go to the local poor as
dividends, the remainder towards building
more bridges. Indeed, that bridge would
likely be the first of many. An array of infrastructure projects, such as roads, highways,
airports, seaports, and utility companies,
could be built in this manner. Because the
social business model demands that the
company generate ongoing revenues
through its activities—for example, by
charging tolls or usage fees on its bridges
(usually with special lower rates for the
poor)—the initial grant should lead to a
continuing, ever-replenished revenue
stream, ultimately producing more social
bang for the donor’s buck.
Currently, inertia is the problem. Once
the concept of social business is included in
economic theory and taught in business
schools around the globe, thousands of people will come forward to invest in social
11
businesses. To connect investors with social
businesses, we will need to create a social
stock market to trade shares of these entities. An investor would come to this stock
exchange to find a social business, which has
a mission to his or her liking—just as someone who wants to make money goes to the
existing stock market. Investors motivated
by the desire to promote particular social
goals would use this market to channel
funds into social businesses that promote
these ends. The values of shares in specific
social businesses would rise and fall along
with the results, both financial and social, of
the underlying businesses. Social businesses
that gain a reputation for producing powerful social benefits—operating schools for atrisk kids in poor neighborhoods, for example, or providing affordable, high-quality
health care to families in low-income communities—while also generating strong,
sustainable revenue flows through astute,
creative management will become the
equivalent of blue-chip stocks, attracting
abundant investment money.
To help a social stock exchange perform
properly, we will need to create ratings
agencies, standardization of terminology,
definitions, impact measurement tools, reporting formats, and new financial publications (perhaps even The Social Wall Street
Journal?) and electronic media to provide
up-to-the-minute information about news
and financial developments affecting social
businesses.
Worst Crises, Best Opportunities
The crises we face offer us all a valuable lesson in the inter-connectedness of the human
family. In a world where economic development in the South is driven, in part, by stable financial markets and thriving
economies in the North, the fate of Lehman
Brothers and of poor sisters working in the
garment factory in Bangladesh are linked.
12
In a world where agricultural markets are
global, the fate of a rice farmer in
Bangladesh, a maize farmer in Mexico, and a
corn farmer in Iowa are all intertwined. And
while the past few decades may have benefited a few at the expense of many others, in
the long run, only policies that allow all the
peoples of the world to share in the progress
will produce long-term security for anyone.
Poverty is not created by poor people; it
is an artificial imposition on individuals and
families with fewer resources than others.
Poor people are endowed with the same unlimited potential for creativity and energy as
any human being in any station of life, anywhere in the world. It is only a question of
removing the barriers faced by the poor so
that they can unleash their creativity and intelligence in the service of humanity. They
can change their lives—if only we could
give them the same opportunities that we
have. Social business and creative, sympathetic economic actors—across all sectors—
are the quickest avenue to this end.
Poverty does not belong in civilized society. It belongs in a museum where our
children and grandchildren will go to see
what inhumanities people had to suffer, and
where they will ask themselves how their
ancestors allowed such a condition to persist
for so long. We’ve accomplished so much
thus far: eradicating diseases, outlawing
slavery, raising crop yields dramatically.
Eliminating poverty is our next great challenge. Now is the time to face these deeply
linked global, economic, and social crises in
a well-planned and well-managed fashion.
This is a unique historical moment. From
the ashes a new society can be built, and the
present crises allow us the opportunity to
design and build a new economic and financial architecture so that this type of catastrophe will never recur. Only by achieving
this can we lay a solid foundation for the
security and peace of future generations.
•
WORLD POLICY JOURNAL • SUMMER 2009
T H E W I L S O N Q U A R T E R LY
The Micromagic
of Microcredit
The millions of tiny loans microcredit banks make to the world’s poor
do not work the miracles some advocates claim. But like the Wizard
of Oz, microcredit does not need to be magic to do a great deal of good.
BY KAROL BOUDREAUX AND TYLER COWEN
Microcredit has star power. In 2006, the
Nobel Committee called it “an important liberating force”
and awarded the Nobel Peace Prize to Muhammad Yunus,
the “godfather of microcredit.” The actress Natalie Portman is a believer too; she advocates support for the Village
Banking Campaign on its MySpace page. The end of
poverty is “just a mouse click away,” she promises. A button on the site swiftly redirects you to paypal.com, where
you can make a contribution to microcredit initiatives.
After decades of failure, the world’s aid organizations
seem to think they have at last found a winning idea. The
United Nations declared 2005 the “International Year of
Microcredit.” Secretary-General Kofi Annan declared
that providing microloans to help poor people launch
small businesses recognizes that they “are the solution,
not the problem. It is a way to build on their ideas,
energy, and vision. It is a way to grow productive enterprises, and so allow communities to prosper.”
Many investors agree. Hundreds of millions of dolKarol Boudreaux is a senior research fellow at the Mercatus Center at
George Mason University. Tyler Cowen is a professor of economics at
George Mason University and author of Discover Your Inner Economist:
Use Incentives to Fall in Love, Survive Your Next Meeting, and Motivate
Your Dentist (2007).
lars are flowing into microfinance from international
financial institutions, foundations, governments, and,
most important, private investors—who increasingly
see microfinance as a potentially profitable business
venture. Private investment through special “microfinance investment vehicles” alone nearly doubled in
2005, from $513 million to $981 million.
On the charitable side, part of microcredit’s appeal
lies in the fact that the lending institutions can fund
themselves once they are launched. Pierre Omidyar, the
founder of eBay, explains that you can begin by investing $60 billion in the world’s poorest people, “and then
you’re done!”
But can microcredit achieve the massive changes its
proponents claim? Is it the solution to poverty in the
developing world, or something more modest—a way to
empower the poor, particularly poor women, with some
control over their lives and their assets?
On trips to Africa and India we have talked to
lenders, borrowers, and other poor people to try to
understand the role microcredit plays in their lives. We
met people like Stadile Menthe in Botswana. Menthe is,
in many ways, the classic borrower. A single mother
Wi n t e r 2 0 0 8 ■ Wi l s o n Q ua r t e r l y
27
Microcredit
90 percent in Asia to less than a third in the Middle East.
While 70 percent of microcredit borrowers are in
Asia, the institution has spread around the world; Latin
America and sub-Saharan Africa account for 14 and 10
percent of the number of borrowers, respectively. Some
of the biggest microfinance institutions include Grameen
Bank, ACCION International, and Pro Mujer of Bolivia.
The average loan size
varies, usually in proportion to the income level
THERE’S A PUZZLE at the heart of microof the home country. In
Rwanda, a typical loan
credit: How can people in new businesses
might be $50 to $200; in
Romania, it is more likely
growing at 20 percent annually afford to pay
to be $2,500 to $5,000.
Often there is no explicit
interest rates as high as 100 percent?
collateral. Instead, the
banks lend to small
groups of about five people, relying on peer pressure for repayment. At mandaincome and made a better life for herself and her daughtory weekly meetings, if one borrower cannot make her
ter. But how many borrowers are like Menthe? In our
payment, the rest of the group must come up with the
judgment, she is the exception, not the norm. Yes, microcash.
credit is mostly a good thing. Very often it helps keep borThe achievements of microcredit, however, are not
rowers from even greater catastrophes, but only rarely
quite what they seem. There is, for example, a puzzling fact
does it enable them to climb out of poverty.
at the heart of the enterprise. Most microcredit banks
The modern story of microcredit began 30 years ago,
charge interest rates of 50 to 100 percent on an annualwhen Yunus—then an economics professor at Chittagong
ized basis (loans, typically, must be paid off within weeks
University in southeastern Bangladesh—set out to apply
or months). That’s not as scandalous as it sounds—local
his theories to improving the lives of the poor in the
moneylenders demand much higher rates. The puzzle is
nearby village of Jobra. He began in 1976 by lending $27
a matter of basic economics: How can people in new
to a group of 42 villagers, who used the money to develop
businesses growing at perhaps 20 percent annually afford
informal businesses, such as making soap or weaving
to pay interest at rates as high as 100 percent?
baskets to sell at the local market. After the success of the
The answer is that, for the most part, they can’t. By
first experiment, Yunus founded Grameen Bank. Today,
and large, the loans serve more modest ends—laudable,
the bank claims more than five million “members” and a
but not world changing.
loan repayment rate of 98 percent. It has lent out some
$6.5 billion.
At the outset, Yunus set a goal that half of the borrowers would be women. He explained, “The banking
icrocredit does not always lead to the creation
system not only rejects poor people, it rejects women. . . .
of small businesses. Many microlenders
Not even one percent of their borrowers are women.” He
refuse to lend money for start-ups; they insist
soon discovered that women were good credit risks, and
that a business already be in place. This suggests that the
good at managing family finances. Today, more than 95
business was sustainable to begin with, without a
percent of Grameen Bank’s borrowers are women. The
microloan. Sometimes lenders help businesses to grow,
UN estimates that women make up 76 percent of microbut often what they really finance is spending and
credit customers around the world, varying from nearly
consumption.
with little formal education, she borrowed money to
expand the small grocery store she runs on a dusty road
on the outskirts of Botswana’s capital city, Gaborone.
Menthe’s store has done well, and she has expanded
into the lucrative business of selling phone cards. In
fact, she’s been successful enough that she has built two
rental homes next to her store. She has diversified her
M
28
Wi l s o n Q ua r t e r l y ■ Wi n t e r 2 0 0 8
Microcredit
That is not to say that
the poor are out shopping
for jewelry and fancy
clothes. In Hyderabad,
India, as in many other
places, we saw that loans
are often used to pay for a
child’s doctor visit. In the
Tanzanian capital of Dar es
Salaam, Joel Mwakitalu,
who runs the Small Enterprise Foundation, a local
microlender, told us that 60
percent of his loans are
used to send kids to school;
40 percent are for investments. A study of microcredit in Indonesia found
that 30 percent of the borrowed money was spent on
some form of consumption.
Sometimes consumption and investment are one
and the same, such as when
parents send their children
to school. Indian borrowers often buy mopeds and
motorbikes—they are fun
to ride but also a way of getting to work. Cell phones
are used to call friends but
also to run businesses.
Bangladesh’s Grameen Bank lends small amounts of money to groups of poor borrowers,who,like these women,
For better or worse, attend weekly meetings where they repay their loans. If one cannot pay, the others make up the difference.
microborrowing often
Commentators often seem to assume that the experientails a kind of bait and switch. The borrower claims
ence of borrowing and lending is completely new for the
that the money is for a business, but uses it for other purpoor. But moneylenders have offered money to the world’s
poses. In effect, the cash allows a poor entrepreneur to
poor for millennia, albeit at extortionate rates of interest.
maintain her business without having to sacrifice the life
A typical moneylender is a single individual, well-known
or education of her child. In that sense, the money is for
in his neighborhood or village, who borrows money from
the business, but most of all it is for the child. Such lifehis wealthier connections and in turn lends those funds to
saving uses for the funds are obviously desirable, but it
individuals in need, typically people he knows personally.
is also a sad reality that many microcredit loans help borBut that personal connection is rarely good for a break; a
rowers to survive or tread water more than they help
moneylender may charge 200 to 400 percent interest on
them get ahead. This sounds unglamorous and even
an annualized basis. He will insist on collateral (a televidisappointing, but the alternative—such as no doctor’s
sion, for instance), and resort to intimidation and somevisit for a child or no school for a year—is much worse.
Wi n t e r 2 0 0 8 ■ Wi l s o n Q ua r t e r l y
29
Microcredit
There is, however, an upside to this “bureaucracy.”
In reality, it is the moneylender who is the “micro”
operator. Microcredit is a more formal, institutionalized business relationship. It represents a move up
toward a larger scale of trade and business organization. Microcredit borrowers gain valuable experience
in working within a formal institution. They learn
what to expect from lenders and fellow borrowers, and
they learn what is expected of themselves. This experience will be a help
should they ever graduate
to commercial credit or
have other dealings with
IF YOUR SAVINGS ARE INVESTED in a
the formal financial
world.
cow, relatives can’t ask for a small piece of it.
The comparison to
moneylending brings up
another important feature
of microcredit. Though its users avoid the kind of intimlife for the planet’s bottom billion even worse by reducidation employed by moneylenders, microcredit could
ing their cash flow. Karnani cites the high interest
not work without similar incentives. The lender does not
rates that microlenders charge and points out that “if
demand collateral, but if you can’t pay your share of the
poor clients cannot earn a greater return on their
group loan, your fellow borrowers will come and take
investment than the interest they must pay, they will
your TV. That enforcement process can lead to abuses,
become poorer as a result of microcredit, not wealthbut it is a gentler form of intimidation than is exercised
ier.” But the real question has never been credit vs. no
by the moneylender. If nothing else, the group members
credit; rather, it is moneylender vs. modern microknow that at the next meeting any one of them might be
credit. Credit can bring some problems, but microthe one unable to repay her share of the loan.
credit is easing debt burdens more than it is increasIf borrowers are using microcredit for consumption
ing them.
and not only to improve a small business, how do they
At microlender SERO Lease and Finance in Tanrepay? Most borrowers are self-employed and work in
zania, borrower Margaret Makingi Marwa told us
the informal sector of the economy. Their incomes are
that she prefers working with a microfinance instituoften erratic; small, unexpected expenses can make
tion to working with a moneylender. Moneylenders
repayment impossible in any given week or month. In
demand quick repayment at high interest rates. At
the countryside, farmers have seasonal incomes and litSERO, Marwa can take six months or a year to pay off
tle cash for long periods of time.
her lease contract. Given that her income can vary and
Borrowers manage, at least in part, by relying on
that she may not have money at hand every month, she
family members and friends to help out. In some
prefers to have a longer-term loan.
cases, the help comes in the form of remittances from
Moneylenders do offer some advantages, especially
abroad. Remittances that cross national borders now
in rural areas. Most important, they come up with
total more than $300 billion yearly. A recent study in
cash on the spot. If your child needs to go to the docTanzania found that microcredit borrowers get 34
tor right now, the moneylender is usually only a short
percent of their income from friends and family, some
walk away. Even under the best of circumstances, a
of whom live abroad, but others of whom live in the
microcredit loan can take several days to process, and
city and have jobs in the formal sector. That’s the
the recipient will be required to deal with many documost effective kind of foreign aid, targeted directly at
ments, not to mention weekly meetings.
times violence if he is not repaid on time. The moneylender operates informally, off the books, and usually outside the law.
So compared to the alternative, microcredit is
often a very good deal indeed. Microcredit critics
often miss this point. For instance, Aneel Karnani,
who teaches at the University of Michigan’s business
school, argues that microfinance “misses its mark.”
Karnani says that in some cases microcredit can make
30
Wi l s o n Q ua r t e r l y ■ Wi n t e r 2 0 0 8
Microcredit
the poor and provided by those who understand their
needs.
Here again, microcredit does something that traditional banks do not. A commercial bank typically will not
lend to people who work in the informal sector, precisely
because their erratic incomes make them risky bets.
The loan officer at a commercial bank does not care
that your brother in Doha is sending money each month
to help you out. But a microcredit institution cares only
that you come to your weekly meeting with a small sum
in hand for repayment. Because of microcredit, families
can leverage one person’s ability to find work elsewhere
to benefit the entire group.
Sometimes microcredit leads to more savings rather
than more debt. That sounds paradoxical, but borrowing in one asset can be a path toward (more efficient) saving in other assets.
To better understand this puzzle, we must set aside
some of our preconceptions about how saving operates
in poor countries, most of all in rural areas. Westerners typically save in the form of money or moneydenominated assets such as stocks and bonds. But in
poor communities, money is often an ineffective
medium for savings; if you want to know how much
net saving is going on, don’t look at money. Banks may
be a daylong bus ride away or may be plagued, as in
Ghana, by fraud. A cash hoard kept at home can be
lost, stolen, taken by the taxman, damaged by floods,
or even eaten by rats. It creates other kinds of problems as well. Needy friends and relatives knock on the
door and ask for aid. In small communities it is often
very hard, even impossible, to say no, especially if you
have the cash on hand.
People who have even extremely modest wealth are
also asked to perform more community service, or to pay
more to finance community rituals and festivals. In rural
Guerrero State, in Mexico, for example, one of us
(Cowen) found that most people who saved cash did not
manage to hold on to it for more than a few weeks or
even days. A dollar saved translates into perhaps a quarter of that wealth kept. It is as if cash savings faces an
implicit “tax rate” of 75 percent.
Under these kinds of conditions, a cow (or a goat or
pig) is a much better medium for saving. It is sturdier
than paper money. Friends and relatives can’t ask for
small pieces of it. If you own a cow, it yields milk, it can
plow the fields, it produces dung that can be used as fuel
or fertilizer, and in a pinch it can be slaughtered and
turned into saleable meat or simply eaten. With a small
loan, people in rural areas can buy that cow and use cash
that might otherwise be diverted to less useful purposes
to pay back the microcredit institution. So even when
microcredit looks like indebtedness, savings are going up
rather than down.
M
icrocredit is making people’s lives better
around the world. But for the most part, it
is not pulling them out of poverty. It is
hard to find entrepreneurs who start with these tiny
loans and graduate to run commercial empires. Bangladesh, where Grameen Bank was born, is still a desperately poor country. The more modest truth is that
microcredit may help some people, perhaps earning
$2 a day, to earn something like $2.50 a day. That
may not sound dramatic, but when you are earning
$2 a day it is a big step forward. And progress is not
the natural state of humankind; microcredit is important even when it does nothing more than stave off
decline.
With microcredit, life becomes more bearable and
easier to manage. The improvements may not show
up as an explicit return on investment, but the benefits are very real. If a poor family is able to keep a
child in school, send someone to a clinic, or build up
more secure savings, its well-being improves, if only
marginally. This is a big part of the reason why poor
people are demanding greater access to microcredit
loans. And microcredit, unlike many charitable services, is capable of paying for itself—which explains
why the private sector is increasingly involved. The
future of microcredit lies in the commercial sector,
not in unsustainable aid programs. Count this as
another benefit.
If this portrait sounds a little underwhelming, don’t
blame microcredit. The real issue is that we so often
underestimate the severity and inertia of global poverty.
Natalie Portman may not be right when she says that
an end to poverty is “just a mouse click away,” but she’s
right to be supportive of a tool that helps soften some
of poverty’s worst blows for many millions of desperate people. ■
Wi n t e r 2 0 0 8 ■ Wi l s o n Q ua r t e r l y
31
International Organization Foundation
Conditioning the Effects of Aid: Cold War Politics, Donor Credibility, and Democracy in
Africa
Author(s): Thad Dunning
Source: International Organization, Vol. 58, No. 2 (Spring, 2004), pp. 409-423
Published by: Cambridge University Press on behalf of the International Organization
Foundation
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3877863
Accessed: 15-12-2016 19:44 UTC
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
Cambridge University Press, University of Wisconsin Press, International
Organization Foundation, The MIT Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to International Organization
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid:
Cold War Politics, Donor Credibility,
and Democracy in Africa
Thad Dunning
Abstract The effect of foreign aid on regime type in recipient countries remains
widely debated. In this research note, I argue that a recent focus on "moral hazard"
has distracted attention from another mechanism linking foreign aid to domestic po-
litical institutions. During the Cold War, donors' geopolitical objectives diminished
the credibility of threats to condition aid on the adoption of democratic reforms. The
demise of the Soviet Union and the end of the Cold War, on the other hand, enhanced the effectiveness of Western aid conditionality. I reanalyze an important recent study and demonstrate that the small positive effect of foreign aid on democracy
in sub-Saharan African countries between 1975 and 1997 is limited to the post-Cold
War period. This new empirical evidence underscores the importance of geopolitical
context in conditioning the causal impact of development assistance, and the evidence confirms that the end of the Cold War marked a watershed in the politics of
foreign aid in Africa.
What is the impact of foreign aid on democracy and regime type in recipient countries? This question has become an important research topic with significant policy implications, yet the effect of aid on local political institutions remains widely
debated. While some analysts suggest that aid "conditionality" may further the
adoption of democratic reforms in recipient countries,1 others claim that aid creates a "moral hazard" 2 for authoritarian local politicians, who pursue goals at odds
with the aims of foreign donors. For these latter analysts, aid simply provides a
source of income with which autocratic leaders may repress or co-opt local popu-
I would like to thank Henry Brady, Jennifer Bussell, Ruth Berins Collier, David Collier, Robert
Powell, Jason Seawright, Beth Simmons, Laura Stoker, and two anonymous reviewers for their comments. I am also grateful to Arthur Goldsmith for sharing his data. Any errors are my own.
1. Goldsmith 2001.
2. The concept of moral hazard was first developed in the context of economic analyses of insu
ance. In this framework, the problem of moral hazard occurs not only because insured agents exerci
power over the probability or risk of the bad outcome against which they are insured, but also becau
the insurance company has a limited ability to monitor the agents' actions because of informatio
asymmetries.
International Organization 58, Spring 2004, pp. 409-423
DOI: 10.1017/S0020818304582073
0 2004 by The IO Foundation.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
410 International Organization
lations' demands for democratization.3 Scholars have also disagreed about the ob-
jectives of donor countries and international organizations themselves. Is the
promotion of democracy really a main priority for donors, or do geopolitical factors instead cause donors to overlook undemocratic practices and allocate aid to
strategic, if autocratic, allies?4
Recent attempts to evaluate the empirical record have produced a growing body
of evidence that is, unfortunately, inconclusive.5 In this research note, I argue that
a recent focus on "moral hazard" has distracted attention from another mechanism
linking foreign aid to local political institutions: the way in which global geopolitics may limit the feasibility of aid "conditionality." During the Cold War, foreign
donors prioritized strategic considerations and the spread of their political influence in sub-Saharan Africa. These geopolitical objectives, however, may have diminished the credibility of donors' threats to make the disbursement of further aid
conditional on the adoption of domestic democratic reforms. In contrast, the end
of the Cold War may have reduced the influence of geopolitical criteria on donors' allocation of aid and made the threats of Western donors to withhold aid
more credible. Aid conditionality may, therefore, have become increasingly possible and effective after the end of the Cold War.
If this argument is correct, one should expect the causal impact of aid on democracy to diverge in the Cold War and post-Cold War periods. While many qualitative studies have suggested that the end of the Cold War marked a watershed
in the politics of aid in Africa, statistical studies have failed to account for this
potential source of heterogeneity in cross-section time-series analyses. In what follows below, I reanalyze an important recent study,6 which found a positive, statistically significant relationship between official development assistance (ODA) from
Western countries and the level of democracy in forty-eight sub-Saharan African
countries between 1975 and 1997. Using data obtained from the author of that
study, I divide the cases into two time periods and then add to the regression model
a new dichotomous control variable to reflect whether recipient countries had a
client relationship with the former Soviet Union. I find that, in the period from
1975 to 1986, no statistically significant relationship emerges between ODA and
democracy.7 By contrast, for the period from 1987 to 1997, the relationship be-
tween aid and democracy is positive and statistically significant, while a Chow
3. See Braiutigam 2000; Devarajan et al. 2001; Killick 1998; Maren 1997; and Moore 1998.
4. See Ake 1996; and Hook 1998.
5. For recent arguments, see Abrahamsen 2000; Briiutigam 2000; Devarajan et al. 2001; Easterly
2001; Hook 1998; Lancaster 1999; Maren 1997; and Moore 1998.
6. Goldsmith 2001.
7. In Goldsmith's 2001 study, the dependent variable is alternately described as "good governance,
"due process," "rule of law," "state capacity," "political freedom," and "democracy." In this article,
stick to the terms "democracy" and "regime type" and operationalize this dependent variable usin
scores on the scale developed by Freedom House. Although democracy remains a contested concep
the Freedom House index is widely accepted as one of the best empirical indicators of political demo
racy. See Diamond 1999, 12.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 411
test rejects the hypothesis of equality of coefficients across the two periods. The
variable measuring the influence of the Soviet Union is statistically significant and
negatively associated with democracy in the earlier period, while the same variable has a positive and statistically significant coefficient in the later period.
These findings raise several empirical and theoretical issues for debates about
the impact of foreign aid. In the following section, I derive the logic of the theoretical argument. Because there is no a priori reason to expect the allegedly "perverse" effects of aid to strengthen or weaken over time, the "moral hazard" or
"perversity" thesis makes no prediction about divergence in the relationship between aid and regime type across historical periods. In contrast, the causal mechanism I highlight here suggests that the impact of Western aid on democracy in
Africa should vary systematically between the Cold War and post-Cold War eras.
This logic therefore provides an initial way to distinguish empirically the "moral
hazard" and the "credible commitment" mechanisms. In the subsequent section, I
present statistical evidence that the positive relationship between aid and democracy in Africa is limited to the post-Cold War period, lending support to the "credible commitment" story and underscoring the importance of global geopolitical
context in conditioning the impact of aid.
Foreign Aid, Democracy, and the Credibility
of Aid Conditionality
Why might one expect the causal relationship between foreign aid and regime
type to diverge in the Cold War and post-Cold War periods? The essence of the
difficulty of using aid to promote democracy may lie not so much in an informational asymmetry between donors and aid recipients, as the "moral hazard" argument made by many prominent critics of aid would suggest,8 but rather in the lack
of credibility of donors' commitment to reform. When two opposing and competing donors (or groups of donors) such as the Soviet Union and the West vie for
influence and clients, aid-receiving countries enjoy greater leverage vis-a-vis their
foreign patrons. To the extent that donors actually prefer to promote democracy
among recipient countries, threats to make aid conditional on the fulfillment of
democratic reforms may not be credible, because withholding aid from autocratic
countries could mean losing clients to the other Cold War power. In other words,
the geostrategic cost of losing clients may override any perceived benefit from
successfully promoting democratic reforms among recipient countries. Recognizing the resulting incredibility of any threat to condition foreign aid on the adoption of democratizing reforms, the leaders of recipient countries may be unwilling
to make the changes that donors demand. Donors, who trade off the costs of a
lack of democratic reform against the benefits of retaining strategic African clients,
8. For example, Easterly 2002. See also the references in note 3.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
412 International Organization
may nonetheless provide aid to autocratic leaders. One should thus expect no observed association between aid and democracy in this period.
The end of the Cold War could make threats to withhold development assistance to African states more credible, and therefore more effective, in two ways.
First, the diminished geostrategic importance of African clients in the post-Cold
War period would imply that the loss of such clients would impose a negligible
geopolitical cost on powerful donors. Second, the dissolution of the Soviet Union
may not only have removed a geopolitical threat to the West but may have vindicated the liberal values of Western donors, lending them a sense of the possibility
of democratization all over the world. Thus the perceived benefit of promoting
democracy in Sub-Saharan Africa rose even as the cost of losing African clients
declined dramatically. African leaders lost significant leverage with which to resist aid conditionality, because only one donor (or group of donors) offered aid to
them in the post-Cold War period. No longer able to take refuge in balance-ofpower politics, recalcitrant African states could be more effectively pressed to undertake the democratizing reforms that Western donors had de-emphasized during
the Cold War. Proponents and opponents of the "perversity thesis" of foreign aid
alike provide no reason to expect the influence of the putative "moral hazard" to
increase or decrease over time. In contrast, the clear prediction of the credible
commitment story is that aid conditionality should become more effective in the
post-Cold War period. One should therefore expect a positive relationship between aid and democracy in the post-Cold War period.
This causal mechanism and its empirical prediction are supported by the qualitative evidence offered by previous studies of democratic reform in Sub-Saharan
Africa. For example, Claude Ake has described a "legacy of indifference" to democracy among Africa's political leaders, a legacy rooted in both the continent's
colonial past and the attitudes of many African politicians after independence.9
Faced with challenges to their newfound political power, postindependence elites
opted for a unifying developmental ideology that sought to repress internal dissent. Importantly, however, this ideology found obliging complicity from Western
countries that were most concerned with the grand strategies of Cold War politics.
Rather than press for democratization, Ake argues that Western powers "ignored
human rights violations and sought clients wherever they could." 10 This was as
true for the Soviet Union as for the Western powers. At a time when Western donors overlooked their liberal principles and the Soviet Union put priority on the
advancement of socialist and revolutionary vanguard parties, there was little external incentive for African states to undertake democratizing reforms.
Consistent with my claim that threats to withhold aid became more credible as
the importance of retaining African clients diminished, however, Ake points to the
9. Ake 1996.
10. Ibid., 63-64.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 413
significance of Africa's greatly diminished strategic importance for the adoption
of democratic reforms in the post-Cold War period:
The marginalization of Africa has given the West more latitude to conduct its
relations with Africa in a principled way. In the past, the West adopted a posture of indifference to issues of human rights and democracy in Africa in
order to avoid jeopardizing its economic and strategic interests and to facilitate its obsessive search for allies against communism. Now that these concerns have diminished, the West finds itself free to bring its African policies
into greater harmony with its democratic principles."
The failure to tie aid to democratic reforms during the Cold War period, therefore,
stemmed from the geostrategic priorities of donors. On a more fundamental level,
however, the greater "latitude" of the West to demand democratic reforms in the
post-Cold War period may have its source in the credible commitment issue. Once
competition with the Soviet Union for African clients had receded, Western donors could much more credibly threaten to withdraw aid if democratic reforms
were not enacted by recipient states.
If the argument advanced above is correct, one should expect to see the relationship of aid to regime type in Sub-Saharan Africa to be characterized by temporal discontinuity. Previous quantitative studies of the relationship between foreign
aid and democracy have failed to take this source of heterogeneity into account,
instead assuming that parameter coefficients are constant over the two periods. In
the following section, I provide empirical evidence in support of the alternate hypothesis that a structural shift in the effect of aid on democracy occurred with the
end of the Cold War.
The Empirical Evidence: Effects of the Cold War
on Aid and Democracy
In an important recent analysis of the impact of foreign aid on regime type in
sub-Saharan Africa, Goldsmith presents statistical evidence that the principled intentions of foreign donors have, on average, been a "minor net plus" for the cause
of democracy in sub-Saharan Africa.12 Goldsmith regresses Freedom House "Index of Political Freedom" scores on the ratio of ODA'3 to gross national product
11. Ibid., 64.
12. Goldsmith 2001, 124.
13. ODA comprises bilateral loans and grants from Development Assistance Committee (DAC) members, multilateral organizations to which those members contribute, and certain Arab countries, but it
does not include Soviet economic credits to sub-Saharan Africa. The DAC member countries of the
OECD are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland,
Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,
United Kingdom, and United States. ODA includes program, project or food aid, emergency assistance, and peacekeeping assistance or technical cooperation, including loans with a grant element of
more than 25 percent. World Bank 1999, 286.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
414 International Organization
(GNP) for forty-eight sub-Saharan African countries between 1975 and 1997 and
reports positive and statistically significant estimates for contemporaneous and
lagged values of the ODA/GNP variable.14 Accordingly, he concludes that there is
"little evidence to support the claim that foreign aid has made governing ... worse,
as the perversity thesis would have it." 15 I replicate Goldsmith's results in Table 1.
If the theoretical argument suggested in the previous section is correct, however, the positive effect of ODA on the Freedom House scores should be limited
to the post-Cold War period. A look at some descriptive statistics in Table 2 sug-
gests interesting contrasts between the periods from 1975-86 and 1987-97. Because this periodization of the data plays an important role in the multivariate
analysis that follows, a few words of explanation of the break between 1986 and
1987 in Table 2 are in order. My goal was to divide the sample into Cold War and
post-Cold War periods, so 1986-87 might seem like a less natural dividing point
for the data than, say, 1991, the year of the dissolution of the Soviet Union. However, in the context of Cold War battles for clients in Africa, the latter date is
misleading. Heavy Soviet engagement in Africa had already waned by the mid1980s, with the emergence of a "new thinking" in Soviet foreign policy associated
with Mikhail Gorbachev, Eduard Shevardnadze, and others, and the Soviet elite
had distanced itself from Leonid Brezhnev's foreign policy doctrines. This elite
no longer proclaimed, as it once did, the existence of what George Breslauer has
termed "an irreconcilable struggle between imperialism and socialism for the allegiance of Third World peoples." 16 More importantly, by 1986, the period of extensive (and expensive) military support for radical regimes in Angola, Ethiopia,
and elsewhere in sub-Saharan Africa during the 1970s had come to an end.17 Although it is true, as Ake notes, that the United States seemed to have more latitude
to shift its foreign policy goals to a vigorously prodemocracy agenda beginning
only in the early 1990s,18 the effective Soviet withdrawal from sub-Saharan Africa certainly affected Western policy priorities in the region.
Table 2 reports mean values of Freedom House scores and the ratio of ODA to
GNP for each country case during each of the periods. The general trend does not
14. Goldsmith 2001 instruments the ODA variable with a population variable and a dummy variable for having been a French colony, along with the other independent variables in the model, and
uses a two-stage least squares (2SLS) model to correct for possible endogeneity. I conducted a DurbinWu-Hausman test and found that the coefficient of the residual from the OLS regression of ODA on all
other variables in the implied system of equations was not statistically significant, suggesting that the
instrumental variable 2SLS setup may be unnecessary (that is, ordinary least squares estimates may be
consistent). Nonetheless, for ease of comparison with Goldsmith's results, in all the tables in this article, I have reported the results of instrumental variable (2SLS) models. As a robustness check I ran the
analyses with ordinary least squares (OLS) estimators, and the results were substantially the same as
those reported. For more on the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test, see (http://www.stata.com/support/faqs/
stat/endogeneity.html). Accessed 29 December 2003.
15. Goldsmith 2001, 124.
16. Breslauer 1992, 196.
17. Herbst 1990.
18. Ake 1996. See note 11.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 415
TABLE 1. Replicating Goldsmith's findings: Impact of foreign aid and other
variables on Freedom House scores
Variable
Model
1
Model
2
Model
3
ODA/GNP (no lag) .0142*** ODA/GNP (one-year lag) - .0169***
ODA/GNP (five-year lag) - .0237***
COMLAW .7090*** .6995*** .5720***
ETHNIC
.0017
.0021
.0022
GDP PER CAPITA .8470*** .8645*** .8850***
Constant -3.8388*** -4.0041*** -4.132***
Adjusted
N
R2
916
0.21
0.22
880
0.21
711
Note:
This
table
re
the
Freedom
House
scale
in
half-point
include
free
and
co
(see
Diamond
1999
common
law.
ETHN
greater
heterogene
(PPP)
terms
for
th
cating
whether
the
and
3
include
lags
o
For
the
sake
of
com
Goldsmith's
(2001)
r
coefficients
I
obtai
with
the
exception
coefficient
of
GDP
as
in
Goldsmith's
o
*** p < 0.001.
** p < 0.01.
* p < 0.05.
contradict the assertion of a linear relationship between Freedom House scores
and ODA. In the earlier period, Freedom House scores for all cases ranged around
an overall mean of 2.4 on a scale of 1 to 7 (the data was recoded from the normal
Freedom House index so that higher scores indicate greater political and civil
rights), while in the later period the overall mean has increased significantly, from
2.4 to 3.0. As for the relationship of ODA to GNP (which is expressed in Table 2
as a percentage rather than a ratio), between 1975 and 1986, the cases fluctuated
around an overall mean of 13.1, while in the later period between 1987 and 1997,
the cases varied around the mean of 19.8. This aggregate impression may, however, mask distinct trends among subgroups of cases. In the first period, the countries that received the lowest scores on the Freedom House variable included the
socialist-oriented states allied during the Cold War with the Soviet Union, in particular Ethiopia, Mozambique, and Tanzania. In the later period, however, the increase of the ODA/GNP ratio in countries that had received little or no ODA (that
is, aid from the rich, largely Western members of the Development Assistance
Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
416 International Organization
TABLE 2. Freedom House scores and the ratio of ODA to GNP, averaged for
each time period
Mean Freedom Mean Freedom Mean of ODA/GNP Mean of ODA/GNP
House score House score variable (as %) variable (as %)
Country (1975-86) (1987-97) (1975-86) (1987-97)
Angola
1.2
1.5
10.2
Benin
1.2
4.2
7.5
14.0
Botswana 5.5 6.0 11.0 4.1
Burkina Faso 3.0 2.8 12.7 16.9
Burundi 1.5 1.5 12.4 21.5
Cameroon 2.1 2.1 3.6 5.3
Cape
Verde
2.0
5.0
61.3
34.6
Central African Rep. 1.5 3.2 12.9 14.9
Chad
1.5
2.0
14.1
23.0
Comoros 3.5 3.5 33.0 21.2
Congo, Dem. Rep. 1.5 1.7 3.2 5.4
Congo, Rep. 1.6 3.0 6.5 10.2
Cote d'Ivoire 2.6 2.6 2.05 8.5
Djibouti
3.5
2.3
25.6
Equatorial Guinea 1.4 1.0 - 37.4
Eritrea
Ethiopia
1.1
-
2.4
2.8
6.7
-
15.3
Gabon
2.0
3.3
1.8
2.7
Gambia, The 5.3 4.2 27.0 26.7
Ghana
2.8
3.1
3.9
10.1
Guinea
1.25
2.2
12.0
Guinea-Bissau 1.9 3.0 39.4 57.1
Kenya
3.0
2.1
5.9
10.6
Lesotho 3.2 3.3 14.0 11.9
Liberia
2.7
2.0
8.0
Madagascar 2.6 4.2 5.3 13.6
Malawi 1.5 3.0 12.0 27.2
Mali
1.3
4.0
17.8
19.7
Mauritania 1.7 1.7 30.0 24.7
Mauritius 5.7 6.3 3.6 1.8
Mozambique
Namibia
1.25
2.5
3.0
4.9
11.1
0.2
77.5
4.3
Niger 1.5 2.7 11.7 17.2
Nigeria
3.8
2.3
0.1
0.9
Rwanda
2.0
1.9
12.2
30.9
4.1
11.4
13.7
SZo Tome and Principe 1.9 4.6 21.3 111.0
Senegal
4.0
Seychelles 2.7 3.4 14.9 5.85
Sierra Leone 2.9 2.2 5.3 18.0
Somalia 1.0 1.0 43.9 51.5
South Africa 2.7 4.2 - 0.3
Sudan
2.6
1.5
8.0
8.1
Swaziland
2.8
2.5
7.9
5.5
Tanzania
2.0
2.5
21.6
Togo
1.6
2.3
11.4
12.8
Uganda
2.4
3.0
7.7
14.4
Zambia
2.8
3.8
9.8
25.1
Zimbabwe 3.3 3.0 2.5 6.8
Overall
means
2.4
3.0
13.1
19.8
Note: See the note to Table 1 regarding Freedom H
able for a small number of years. The following stat
these years: Column 2: Djibouti, 1976-86; Namib
97. Column 4: Cape Verde, 1980-86; Ethiopia, 19
1980-86. Column 5: Djibouti, 1992-93; Somalia, 1
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 417
(OECD) during the earlier period is striking. Note for example the case of Tanzania, where ODA went from zero to 22 percent of GNP, or Mozambique, where it
went from 11 to 78 percent.19
These descriptive statistics, along with the theoretical argument advanced in the
previous section, suggest that the positive, statistically significant effect of foreign
aid on democratization that Goldsmith finds may be highly period-dependent. In
his analysis, Goldsmith notes that since 1989 "eighteen African countries (have)
moved up at least one category in the Freedom House ratings."20 He suggests in
passing the possibility that "aid is allocated primarily on geopolitical grounds, and
not as a result of rational humanitarian planning." 21 He even mentions that while
the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID) has formally limited its
assistance to countries that protect human rights and civil liberties since 1975,
"during the Cold War national security considerations often overrode this rule." 22
Yet the statistical analysis does not attempt to take these historical and geopolitical factors into account, nor do the regressions control for period-dependent factors.
Aid, therefore, may have a positive impact on democracy only in the later period. To test the argument, in Table 3, I again ran the regression described in Table 1,
dividing the sample observations into the two periods presented in Table 2. More-
over, I added to the earlier model a dichotomous dummy variable measuring
whether a country was a client state of the Soviet Union during the Cold War.23
The proxy for this relationship is whether the Soviet Union considered a subSaharan African state a "revolutionary democracy" or "socialist-oriented" during
the 1970s and 1980s, a category that includes thirteen states.24 The goal of adding
the SOVIET CLIENT dummy variable to the model specification is twofold. First,
because I am interested in the effect of ODA on democracy, the dummy variable
makes the specification a kind of pseudo-fixed effects model in which the SOVIET
CLIENT variable picks up group-specific factors that may affect the countries that
were socialist during the Cold War and that may be correlated with the included
19. Obviously the ratio of ODA/GNP is affected by changes in the denominator as well as in the
numerator. Nonetheless, the dramatic growth of this ratio in such cases clearly owes to a rise in the
absolute amounts of ODA rather than to a precipitous decline in national income.
20. Goldsmith 2001, 131.
21. Ibid., 140.
22. Ibid., 136.
23. The results reported in Table 3 are robust to the exclusion of the SOVIET CLIENT dummy vari-
able, that is, the sign and statistical significance of the estimated coefficients of the independent vari-
ables in the restricted model, which I do not report to save space, are largely identical to those in
Table 3.
24. The countries are Angola, Benin, Cape Verde, Congo, Ethiopia, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Madagascar, Mozambique, Seychelles, and Tanzania ("revolutionary democracies"); and Mali and Zambia
("socialist-oriented states"). Guinea became a "capitalist-oriented" country from the Soviet standpoint
in 1984, but I include it as a Cold War client state of the Soviet Union, because the categorization
covered most of the first period in my analysis. Somalia, on the other hand, was a "revolutionary
democracy" (and thus in favor with the Soviet Union) before 1977, but the Soviets categorized it as
"capitalist-oriented" after that year; accordingly, it is coded as a 0 in the dichotomous scheme used
here. For data and the sources of these categories, see Albright 1991, 38-39.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
418 International Organization
TABLE 3. Disaggregating the findings: Cold War versus post-Cold War periods
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
Variable (1975-86) (1975-86) (1975-86) (1987-97) (1987-97) (1987-97)
ODA/GNP (no lag) .0088 - - .0120***
ODA/GNP (one-year lag) - .0073 -- .0154*** ODA/GNP (five-year lag) - - .0031 -- .0220***
SOVIET CLIENT -.5650*** -.5532*** -.5255** .4342** .4449** .5008***
COMLAW .9597*** .9766*** 1.009"** .3976** .4039** .3478*
ETHNIC
.0009
.0010
.0020
.0011
.0014
.0008
GDP PER CAPITA .7218*** .7092*** .6770*** .9569*** .9908*** .9981***
Constant -2.994*** -2.895 -2.741*** -4.366*** -4.696*** -4.74***
Adjusted
N
444
R2
404
.34
.34
250
.35
472
.18
.20
477
.22
463
Chow test 9.127"** 17.73*** 51.827***
Note: This table uses an instrumental variables (two-stag
dummy variable, coded 1 for the thirteen countries that w
and otherwise coded 0. See note 24. The definition of cl
were considered "capitalist-oriented" by the Soviets but no
Union during the 1970s and 1980s. For example, Nigeri
credits between 1975 and 1979, compared to the $17.5 m
explanatory notes are as in Table 1.
The Chow test for structural change, which is an F-test,
the two periods. The error sum of squares in the unrestric
model where the coefficients are restricted to equality acr
the specification in Table 1 to make the number of para
parameters in the unrestricted model above. Tests in w
models yielded similar results.
*** p < 0.001.
** p < 0.01.
*p < 0.05.
independent variables. Secondly, however, it is important to bear in mind that t
source of foreign aid considered here is exclusively Western, because the data co
from the Development Assistance Committee of the OECD.25 The group-specif
intercept on the SOVIET CLIENT dummy variable can then be interpreted as a ki
of proxy for the unmeasured influence of Soviet rather than Western aid, at le
during the Cold War period.26
Between 1975 and 1986, no statistically significant effect of ODA on the dep
dent variable emerges for any of the three models. By contrast, the coefficient
ODA in the 1987-97 period is positive and statistically significant at the .001 le
in each of the three models. A Chow test for structural change strongly rejects
null hypothesis that coefficients are equal in the two periods. Furthermore, th
25. As reported in World Bank 1999. See note 13 on the components of ODA.
26. Because of severe missing data, it was not possible to incorporate the actual amounts of So
aid into the analysis.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 419
results are robust to a variety of departures from ordinary least square (OLS) assumptions about the error term.27
What inferences can one draw from these results? First, they lend support to the
hypothesis that the impact of aid on regime type varies between the Cold War and
post-Cold War periods. The strong association between the ODA variable and Free-
dom House scores around the beginning of the 1990s is apparently driving the
statistically significant, positive impact of ODA on democracy that was reported
in Table 1 for the entire period from 1975-97. For purposes of this article, the
most important point is that ODA stemming from Western countries and certain
Arab countries fails to have a statistically significant impact on political freedoms
in sub-Saharan Africa from 1975 to 1986. The positive and statistically significant
association of the same variables between 1987 and 1997 suggests that the time
period clearly matters.
Second, the sign of the coefficients on the SOVIET CLIENT dummy variable are
notable. In the earlier period, the estimates for this variable are negative and statistically significant in all three of the models, while in the later period they are
statistically significant and positively signed. The negative sign in the earlier period may suggest the importance of the unmeasured Soviet aid to such states and
certainly is consistent with the theoretical argument I have made above. Just as
interesting, however, is the finding that having been a Soviet client state during
the Cold War was statistically significantly and positively associated with democratization in the post-Cold War period. This is consistent with the argument that
the end of the Cold War precipitated a particularly marked shift among formerly
Soviet client states and suggests that previous cross-sectional time-series studies
of the impact of aid on democracy in Africa have failed to account for this source
of heterogeneity in sample periods.
The evidence in Table 3, therefore, supports the claim that the ability of West-
ern lenders to condition aid on the adoption of reforms increased with the
demise of the Soviet Union. Previous studies have also noted that the end of the
Cold War provided an incentive for international donors to move more vigorously to sanction antidemocratic practices than they had during the Cold War. As
Bratton and Van de Walle explained in their definitive study of regime transitions
in contemporary Africa, "In the post-Cold War world, Western diplomacy is generally intolerant of military intervention in new democracies. Thus, the 1993 coup
in Burundi was greeted by the suspension of most foreign aid, as was the deci-
27. For example, readers may be skeptical of the least squares sphericality assumptions (nonautocorrelation and homoscedasticity). Using pairwise inclusion of cases to take account of the slightly
unbalanced panel, I estimated the model with panel-corrected standard errors (see Beck and Katz 1995),
which correct for panel heteroscedasticity and contemporaneous correlation of the errors. For purposes
of comparability with Table 1 and Goldsmith's 2001 results, I report the 2SLS results using uncorrected standard errors in Table 3. However, the sign and statistical significance of the coefficients when
panel-corrected standard errors are used are identical to those reported in Table 3. The full set of results are available from the author on request.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
420 International Organization
sion by the Nigerian military to annul the 1993 elections won by Moshood
Abiola." 28 It is certainly the case that some threats to apply sanctions have not been
followed through in the post-Cold War period and that there have been important
inconsistencies of application. A complex mix of "carrots" and "sticks" has been
applied, as in the case of Daniel Arap Moi's Kenya,29 and some undemocratic practices have gone unsanctioned, to the chagrin of many critics of international donor
organizations. Nonetheless, Goldsmith's assertion that aid may be a "minor net
plus" 30 for democracy may be right-in the post-Cold War period alone.
The results are also consistent with country-level claims that the demise of the
Soviet Union produced a particularly dramatic shift among formerly MarxistLeninist countries. For example, Bratton and Van de Walle observe that "the
greatest gains in political liberalization (between 1988 and 1992) were made by
governments that started from a very low base of rights observance and that aban-
doned an ideological commitment to Marxism-Leninism (e.g., B6nin, Cape Verde,
Congo, Ethiopia, Mozambique, and Angola)." 31 A prototypical case is B6nin, which
"may lay claim to the most extensive and impressive peaceful political transformation of any formerly one-party African state in the present period." 32 Nwajiaku
writes that although the Marxist-Leninist years had isolated B6nin from Western
aid, the collapse of the Soviet Union's external financing for African states and
the entry of French donors in the 1980s gave French donors, backed by the Bretton Woods institutions (the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund),
significant power to promote reforms in B6nin.33 For example, "the limited relaxation of repressive authoritarian practices in the later 1980s and early 1990s precipitated by the loan-attached conditionalities of international donors, which required
at least the show of greater 'political transparency,' liberty, and respect of human
rights, also encouraged the growth of opposition groups. Greater political openness thus stemmed from a more pronounced need to attract external assistance in
order to 'manage' the worsening economic crisis by permitting at least the voicing
of discontent ... as developments in Eastern Europe indicated that political authoritarianism was out of fashion." 34 By the end of 1989, "given the country's
desperate need for an inflow of funds to alleviate the increasingly tense situation,
the French Ministry of Co-operation was able to lean heavily on (Benin's) K6r6kou,
virtually forcing him to introduce changes in order to break the economic and
political deadlock." 35
28. Bratton and Van de Walle 1997, 241.
29. Goldsmith 2001.
30. Ibid., 124.
31. Bratton and Van de Walle 1997, 160; see also Herbst 1990.
32. Allen 1992, cited in Bratton and Van de Walle 1997.
33. Nwajiaku 1994.
34. Ibid., 434.
35. Ibid., 438. It should nonetheless be noted that although French President Frangois Mitterand
was widely given credit for promoting aid conditionality for Africa at the La Baule Franco-American
Summit in 1991, French policies have been criticized for their inconsistency. Bratton and Van de Walle
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 421
Some skeptics could justifiably argue that the empirical models do not completely specify the covariates of democracy in sub-Saharan Africa. The amount of
variance explained (as reflected in the R-squared statistic) is fairly low for a timeseries cross-section model and substantially lower during the later period than the
earlier, suggesting perhaps an important role for un-modeled factors during the
later period. A more complete predictive model might include a measure of dependence on natural resource endowments (which should be negatively associated with
democracy according to the "resource curse" literature36), or a measure of the independent role of domestic democracy movements in a number of countries. However, such un-modeled factors are quite plausibly uncorrelated with the included
independent variables, reducing the chances of specification bias.37 In any case,
the goal of the empirical testing in this research note has not been to provide a
complete predictive model of democracy in sub-Saharan Africa but rather to ask
whether the structural impact of aid on regime type varies systematically with time
period. Here, the answer of the model is clearly affirmative.
Conclusion: Foreign Aid and Democracy
Reconsidered
The findings I present in this research note make two contributions to the deb
concerning the effectiveness of foreign aid conditionality. First, the analysis s
gests that the causal impact of aid on regime type may be historically conting
in ways not appreciated by previous research. The relationship between foreign
aid and democracy in sub-Saharan Africa appears to be highly conditioned by t
distinction between the Cold War and post-Cold War periods. Earlier empir
research, therefore, may have reported misleading averages that in fact maske
temporally defined shifts in causal patterns across subgroups of cases.
Secondly, the causal mechanism to which I have pointed to explain this diver
gence is quite distinct from the increasingly popular "moral hazard" or "perver
sity" theory of aid. Whether the latter theory is correct or incorrect, it clearly mak
no prediction about temporal variation in the effect of aid on democracy. In oth
words, there is no a priori reason to expect the allegedly "perverse" effect of
1997, 241, note that "Democratic B6nin actually saw its French aid decline in the year following
transition, whereas recalcitrant authoritarian regimes in Togo, Cameroon, and Zaire all benefited fr
French aid increases during the same period."
36. See Ross 2001.
37. See also note 14. Little scholarship has suggested that aid allocation in Africa (at least un
recently) has been driven by the natural resource endowments of recipients. As for internal demo
movements, much of the existing literature has stressed the extent to which the culmination of d
tic democracy movements, though contemporaneous with the end of the Cold War, was independen
it. Ake 1996, for example, points out that internal struggles for democratization in a number o
Saharan African countries independently came to fruition just as the ideological struggle of Eas
West in the Third World came to an end. See also Bratton and Van de Walle 1997.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
422 International Organization
on democracy to strengthen or weaken over time. The predictions of my credible
commitment story, on the other hand, contain an important temporal dimension,
because the disappearance of the geostrategic threat from the Soviet Union may
have made threats from Western donors to withdraw aid much more credible. The
empirical results I present in this article are consistent with the predictions of the
credible commitment story but not with the "perversity thesis." The results therefore suggest that further theoretical attention should be focused on the issue of
credible commitment in the allocation of foreign aid.
These empirical and theoretical points justify increased attention as well to the
geopolitics of aid provision in future research. In contrast to recent arguments advanced by some of foreign aid's critics, the likelihood that aid may effectively
promote democracy will in fact increase when the role of strategic or geopolitical
factors in allocating aid diminishes. Former World Bank economist William East-
erly recently launched a scathing criticism of donor organizations, entitled "The
Cartel of Good Intentions" in which he states:
among the most popular concepts the aid community has recently discovered
is "selectivity"-the principle that aid will only work in countries with good
economic policies and efficient, squeaky-clean institutions. The moment of
aid donors' conversion on this point supposedly came with the end of the
Cold War, but in truth, selectivity (and other "new" ideas) has been a recurrent aid theme over the last 40 years.... Unfortunately, evidence of a true
conversion on selectivity remains mixed.38
In fact, the suggestion that aid conditionality is a recycled notion may be irrelevant. What may matter is not whether donor "selectivity" is a new idea, or whether
aid will only "work" in countries with institutions that are already "squeakyclean." Instead, a crucial factor may be whether the threats of international donors
to withdraw aid if democratic reforms are not adopted can be made credible and
therefore effective. The theory and evidence presented above suggest that condi-
tioning aid on levels of democracy in recipient countries may only be credible
under certain global geostrategic circumstances-for example, those provided in
Africa by the end of the Cold War. The empirical evidence presented above should
provide a small measure of encouragement to the proponents of foreign aid. At
the same time, for those concerned with promoting democracy in Africa, there is
no guarantee that the propitious conditions posed by the end of the Cold War will
persist. U.S. policymakers have recently begun point out the strategic nature of
West and Central African oil reserves, implying that geopolitical criteria could
play an important role in pending aid allocation decisions.39 The research presented here should thus also sound a note of alarm about the future dangers that
geopolitical factors could pose to the effectiveness of aid conditionality.
38. Easterly 2002.
39. See, for example, James Dao, "In Quietly Courting Africa, U.S. Likes Dowry," New York Times,
19 September 2002, Al.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Conditioning the Effects of Aid 423
References
Abrahamsen, Rita. 2000. Disciplining Democracy: Development Discourse and Good Governance in
Africa. London: Zed Books.
Ake, Claude. 1996. Rethinking African Democracy. In The Global Resurgence of Democracy, 2d ed.,
edited by Larry Diamond and Marc F. Plattner, 63-75. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University
Press.
Albright, David E. 1991. Soviet Economic Development and the Third World. Soviet Studies 43
(1):27-59.
Allen, Chris. 1992. "Goodbye to All That": The Short and Sad Story of Socialism in Benin. Journal of
Communist Studies 8 (2):63-81.
Beck, Nathaniel, and Jonathan N. Katz. 1995. "What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-
Sectional Data." American Political Science Review 89 (3):634-47.
Bratton, Michael, and Nicolas van de Walle. 1997. Democratic Experiments in Africa: Regime Transitions in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Brdiutigam, Deborah. 2000. Aid Dependence and Governance. Stockholm: Almquist and Wiksell
International.
Breslauer, George W. 1992. Explaining Soviet Policy Changes: Politics, Ideology, and Learning. In
Soviet Policy in Africa: From the Old to the New Thinking, edited by George W. Breslauer, 196216. Berkeley: Center for Slavic and East European Studies, University of California, and the
Berkeley-Stanford Program in Soviet Studies.
Devarajan, Shantayanan, David R. Dollar, and Torgny Holmgren, eds. 2001. Aid and Reform in Africa:
Lessons from Ten Case Studies. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Diamond, Larry. 1999. Developing Democracy: Toward Consolidation. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Easterly, William. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists'Adventures and Misadventures in
the Tropics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
- 2002. The Cartel of Good Intentions. Foreign Policy 131 (July/August):40-44.
Goldsmith, Arthur A. 2001. Foreign Aid and Statehood in Africa. International Organization 55
(1):123-48.
Herbst, Jeffrey. 1990. Third World Communism in Crisis: The Fall of Afro-Marxism. Journal of De-
mocracy 1 (3):92-101.
Hook, Steven W. 1998. "Building Democracy" through Foreign Aid: The Limitations of United States
Political Conditionalities, 1992-1996. Democratization 5 (3):156-80.
Killick, Tony, Ramani Gunatilaka, and Ana Marr. 1998. Aid and the Political Economy of Policy Change.
London: Routledge.
Lancaster, Carol. 1999. Aid to Africa: So Much to Do, So Little Done. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Maren, Michael. 1997. Road to Hell: The Ravaging Effects of Foreign Aid and International Charity.
New York: Free Press.
Moore, Mick. 1998. Death Without Taxes: Democracy, State Capacity, and Aid Dependence in
Fourth World. In The Democratic Developmental State: Politics and Institutional Design, edited
Mark Robinson and Gordon White, 84-121. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Nwajiaku, Kathryn. 1994. The National Conferences in Benin and Togo Revisited. Journal of Mod
African Studies 32 (3):429-47.
Ross, Michael. 2001. Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics 53 (3):325-61.
World Bank. 1999. Entering the 21st Century: World Development Report 1999/2000. Washingt
D.C.: World Bank.
This content downloaded from 141.165.253.11 on Thu, 15 Dec 2016 19:44:07 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
The cartel of good intentions
Easterly, William
Foreign Policy; Jul/Aug 2002; 131; ProQuest Central
pg. 40
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
Purchase answer to see full
attachment