Binomial Model and Option Valuation: Part I
ECO 426: Financial Economics
Monica Tran-Xuan
University at Buffalo
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
1/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
2/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
3/ 37
Recap/Intro
▶ Last time we used the concept of replicating portfolio payoffs and the law of one
price to derive the put call parity relationship
P + S0 = C +
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
K
(1 + rf )T
4/ 37
Recap/Intro
▶ Last time we used the concept of replicating portfolio payoffs and the law of one
price to derive the put call parity relationship
P + S0 = C +
K
(1 + rf )T
▶ Today, we’ll talk more about option valuation and then use a simple model to
price options on a stock
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
4/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
5/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Recall payoff of a call option at expiration is
(
ST − K
Payoffcall =
0
if ST > K
if ST ≤ K
or
Payoffcall = max{ST − K , 0}
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
6/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Recall payoff of a call option at expiration is
(
ST − K
Payoffcall =
0
if ST > K
if ST ≤ K
or
Payoffcall = max{ST − K , 0}
▶ Clearly, a lower bound on the value of a call option at any time is zero:
Pcall ≥ 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
6/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Recall payoff of a call option at expiration is
(
ST − K
Payoffcall =
0
if ST > K
if ST ≤ K
or
Payoffcall = max{ST − K , 0}
▶ Clearly, a lower bound on the value of a call option at any time is zero:
Pcall ≥ 0
▶ Can we come up with another lower bound?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
6/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Suppose that the underlying asset is a stock that pays dividend D just before
the expiration date T . ST is the stock price at time T .
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
7/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Suppose that the underlying asset is a stock that pays dividend D just before
the expiration date T . ST is the stock price at time T .
▶ Consider two portfolios:
1. A call option with strike price K on one share of stock that expires at a future
time T
2. The stock plus a loan with repayment K + D at T
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
7/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Suppose that the underlying asset is a stock that pays dividend D just before
the expiration date T . ST is the stock price at time T .
▶ Consider two portfolios:
1. A call option with strike price K on one share of stock that expires at a future
time T
2. The stock plus a loan with repayment K + D at T
▶ Payoff of the first portfolio (call option) at expiration is
Payoff1 =
▶ Payoff of the second portfolio (stock plus loan) at expiration is
Payoff2 =
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
7/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Comparing these payoff, we see that
Payoff1 ≥ Payoff2
∀ST
So the payoff of the portfolio 1 (the option) is always at least as large as the
payoff of the portfolio 2 (stock plus loan) no matter what ST is (i.e., in all states
of the world)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
8/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Comparing these payoff, we see that
Payoff1 ≥ Payoff2
∀ST
So the payoff of the portfolio 1 (the option) is always at least as large as the
payoff of the portfolio 2 (stock plus loan) no matter what ST is (i.e., in all states
of the world)
▶ This means that portfolio 1 should be more expensive to establish today than
portfolio 2
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
8/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Comparing these payoff, we see that
Payoff1 ≥ Payoff2
∀ST
So the payoff of the portfolio 1 (the option) is always at least as large as the
payoff of the portfolio 2 (stock plus loan) no matter what ST is (i.e., in all states
of the world)
▶ This means that portfolio 1 should be more expensive to establish today than
portfolio 2
▶ =⇒ the price of the call today should be greater than or equal to the price of
the stock and the loan today
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
8/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Let S0 represent the price of the stock today and PV (K ) and PV (D) represent
the present values of a risk-free payment of K and D respectively at time T
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Let S0 represent the price of the stock today and PV (K ) and PV (D) represent
the present values of a risk-free payment of K and D respectively at time T
▶ Then we know that
Pcall ≥ S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Let S0 represent the price of the stock today and PV (K ) and PV (D) represent
the present values of a risk-free payment of K and D respectively at time T
▶ Then we know that
Pcall ≥ S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)
▶ Combining the two lower bounds we have on Pcall gives
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)}
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Let S0 represent the price of the stock today and PV (K ) and PV (D) represent
the present values of a risk-free payment of K and D respectively at time T
▶ Then we know that
Pcall ≥ S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)
▶ Combining the two lower bounds we have on Pcall gives
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)}
▶ This is a stronger lower bound on the price of a call
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ Let S0 represent the price of the stock today and PV (K ) and PV (D) represent
the present values of a risk-free payment of K and D respectively at time T
▶ Then we know that
Pcall ≥ S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)
▶ Combining the two lower bounds we have on Pcall gives
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)}
▶ This is a stronger lower bound on the price of a call
▶ What about an upper bound?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ A clear upper bound on the price of a call is S0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
10/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ A clear upper bound on the price of a call is S0
▶ Nobody would pay more than S0 to purchase the right to buy a stock worth S0
today
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
10/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
▶ A clear upper bound on the price of a call is S0
▶ Nobody would pay more than S0 to purchase the right to buy a stock worth S0
today
▶ We can conclude that
max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)} ≤ Pcall ≤ S0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
10/ 37
Bounds on the Price of a Call Option
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
11/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
12/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Question: When (if ever) is it optimal to exercise an American call option on a
stock that pays no dividends before expiration?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Question: When (if ever) is it optimal to exercise an American call option on a
stock that pays no dividends before expiration?
▶ Suppose the price of a stock today is S0 , and an investor has bought a call
option on the stock with strike price K and maturity date T
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Question: When (if ever) is it optimal to exercise an American call option on a
stock that pays no dividends before expiration?
▶ Suppose the price of a stock today is S0 , and an investor has bought a call
option on the stock with strike price K and maturity date T
▶ We already showed that
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)}
▶ Since the stock pays no dividends PV (D) = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Question: When (if ever) is it optimal to exercise an American call option on a
stock that pays no dividends before expiration?
▶ Suppose the price of a stock today is S0 , and an investor has bought a call
option on the stock with strike price K and maturity date T
▶ We already showed that
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K ) − PV (D)}
▶ Since the stock pays no dividends PV (D) = 0
▶ So we have
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )}
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ We already know that whenever S0 < K the call option is never exercised (since
you could just go to the market and buy the stock for S0 )
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ We already know that whenever S0 < K the call option is never exercised (since
you could just go to the market and buy the stock for S0 )
▶ So the only interesting cases are those with S0 ≥ K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ We already know that whenever S0 < K the call option is never exercised (since
you could just go to the market and buy the stock for S0 )
▶ So the only interesting cases are those with S0 ≥ K
▶ Since the investor prefers to have K dollars today than K dollars at date T , we
have that
K > PV (K )
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ We already know that whenever S0 < K the call option is never exercised (since
you could just go to the market and buy the stock for S0 )
▶ So the only interesting cases are those with S0 ≥ K
▶ Since the investor prefers to have K dollars today than K dollars at date T , we
have that
K > PV (K )
▶ Therefore,
S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Since S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K , and Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )}, this tells us that
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )} ≥ S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
15/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Since S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K , and Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )}, this tells us that
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )} ≥ S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K
▶ So
Pcall > S0 − K
And S0 − K is the payoff from exercising the option today
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
15/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Since S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K , and Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )}, this tells us that
Pcall ≥ max{0, S0 − PV (K )} ≥ S0 − PV (K ) > S0 − K
▶ So
Pcall > S0 − K
And S0 − K is the payoff from exercising the option today
▶ So we can conclude that the investor is better off selling the option for Pcall than
exercising it
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
15/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ So we have shown that call options on stocks that pay no dividends are worth
more alive than exercised
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ So we have shown that call options on stocks that pay no dividends are worth
more alive than exercised
▶ For such calls, the right to exercise before maturity is worthless
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ So we have shown that call options on stocks that pay no dividends are worth
more alive than exercised
▶ For such calls, the right to exercise before maturity is worthless
▶ =⇒ all else equal, American calls and European call on stocks that pay no
dividends are worth the same!
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ So we have shown that call options on stocks that pay no dividends are worth
more alive than exercised
▶ For such calls, the right to exercise before maturity is worthless
▶ =⇒ all else equal, American calls and European call on stocks that pay no
dividends are worth the same!
▶ Note that this conclusion fails to hold if a stock pays dividends: the presence of
P(D) in the chain of inequalities would not allow us to conclude that
Pcall > S0 − K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ So we have shown that call options on stocks that pay no dividends are worth
more alive than exercised
▶ For such calls, the right to exercise before maturity is worthless
▶ =⇒ all else equal, American calls and European call on stocks that pay no
dividends are worth the same!
▶ Note that this conclusion fails to hold if a stock pays dividends: the presence of
P(D) in the chain of inequalities would not allow us to conclude that
Pcall > S0 − K
▶ For a stock paying a dividend, the investor may want to exercise early to get the
dividend payment of the stock
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Does this conclusion hold for put option? I.e., are American and European puts
worth the same?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
17/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Does this conclusion hold for put option? I.e., are American and European puts
worth the same?
▶ Unfortunately not. Suppose the price of a stock today is S0 . An investor has
bought a put option on the stock with exercise price K and maturity date T .
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
17/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Does this conclusion hold for put option? I.e., are American and European puts
worth the same?
▶ Unfortunately not. Suppose the price of a stock today is S0 . An investor has
bought a put option on the stock with exercise price K and maturity date T .
▶ Recall that, given the price of the stock today, the payoff from the put would be
(
K − S0 if S0 < K
0
if S0 ≥ K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
17/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Suppose at some t < T the firm issuing the stock goes bankrupt and we have
St = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Suppose at some t < T the firm issuing the stock goes bankrupt and we have
St = 0
▶ Then the payoff of the put cannot get any larger, so exercising is optimal at time
t < T (since exercising the put later means the investor misses out on the
opportunity cost of his money)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Suppose at some t < T the firm issuing the stock goes bankrupt and we have
St = 0
▶ Then the payoff of the put cannot get any larger, so exercising is optimal at time
t < T (since exercising the put later means the investor misses out on the
opportunity cost of his money)
▶ Even in the case where St is small (but not zero), the possible gains from not
exercising are small while the opportunity cost is large (the time-value of money)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 37
Early Exercise
▶ Suppose at some t < T the firm issuing the stock goes bankrupt and we have
St = 0
▶ Then the payoff of the put cannot get any larger, so exercising is optimal at time
t < T (since exercising the put later means the investor misses out on the
opportunity cost of his money)
▶ Even in the case where St is small (but not zero), the possible gains from not
exercising are small while the opportunity cost is large (the time-value of money)
▶ We can conclude that it could be optimal to exercise a put option before
expiration
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
19/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
▶ Assume in what follows we are working with call options on a stock that pays no
dividends.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
▶ Assume in what follows we are working with call options on a stock that pays no
dividends.
▶ Note that even when a call option with expiration date this week is out of the
money, it is not worthless since there exists some non-zero chance that the call
will be in the money until maturity.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
▶ Assume in what follows we are working with call options on a stock that pays no
dividends.
▶ Note that even when a call option with expiration date this week is out of the
money, it is not worthless since there exists some non-zero chance that the call
will be in the money until maturity.
Definition: The intrinsic value of a call option with strike price K and current price
of the underlying asset S0 is
(
S0 − K if S0 ≥ K
IVcall =
0
if S0 < K
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
▶ Assume in what follows we are working with call options on a stock that pays no
dividends.
▶ Note that even when a call option with expiration date this week is out of the
money, it is not worthless since there exists some non-zero chance that the call
will be in the money until maturity.
Definition: The intrinsic value of a call option with strike price K and current price
of the underlying asset S0 is
(
S0 − K if S0 ≥ K
IVcall =
0
if S0 < K
▶ The intrinsic value of a call option is the payoff of the option upon immediate
exercise.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
Definition: The time value of a call option is Pcall − IVcall . The time value of the call
option is the part of the value of the option attributable to the fact that the option
has not expired yet.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
21/ 37
Intrinsic Value and Time Value
Definition: The time value of a call option is Pcall − IVcall . The time value of the call
option is the part of the value of the option attributable to the fact that the option
has not expired yet.
Note: Do not confuse this with the time value of money.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
21/ 37
Table of Contents
Recap
Option Valuation
Early Exercise
Intrinsic and Time Values
Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
22/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Is there a simple model that allows us to price options?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
23/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Is there a simple model that allows us to price options?
▶ Yes, many of the option pricing models that exist require additional
mathematical sophistication, but the important insights from these models can
be presented in a much simpler version, the Binomial Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
23/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Is there a simple model that allows us to price options?
▶ Yes, many of the option pricing models that exist require additional
mathematical sophistication, but the important insights from these models can
be presented in a much simpler version, the Binomial Model
▶ This model will use the concept of replicating portfolio payoffs that we have seen
before to find the (no-arbitrage) price of derivatives
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
23/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Suppose a stock’s price today is S0 = $100. Consider a call option on the stock
that has strike price K = $110 and expiration date 1 year
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Suppose a stock’s price today is S0 = $100. Consider a call option on the stock
that has strike price K = $110 and expiration date 1 year
▶ Assume the risk-free rate is 10%
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Suppose a stock’s price today is S0 = $100. Consider a call option on the stock
that has strike price K = $110 and expiration date 1 year
▶ Assume the risk-free rate is 10%
▶ Suppose after 1 year there are two possible states of the world:
▶ The stock price goes down to S1 = $90
▶ The stock price rises to S1 = $120
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 37
Binomial Model
▶ Suppose a stock’s price today is S0 = $100. Consider a call option on the stock
that has strike price K = $110 and expiration date 1 year
▶ Assume the risk-free rate is 10%
▶ Suppose after 1 year there are two possible states of the world:
▶ The stock price goes down to S1 = $90
▶ The stock price rises to S1 = $120
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 37
Binomial Tree
▶ We can draw a binomial tree to represent this stock
120
S0 = 100
90
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
25/ 37
Binomial Tree
▶ We can draw a binomial tree to represent this stock
120
S0 = 100
90
▶ We can also draw the binomial tree for the payoffs of the call option on this
stock:
10
C
0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
25/ 37
Binomial Tree
▶ We can draw a binomial tree to represent this stock
120
S0 = 100
90
▶ We can also draw the binomial tree for the payoffs of the call option on this
stock:
10
C
0
▶ We want to find C , the price of the call option at time 0.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
25/ 37
Replicating Portfolios
▶ Compare the payoffs of the call option to that of a portfolio consisting of one
share of stock and borrowing $81.82 at the risk-free rate of 10%. The price of
establishing this portfolio is 100 − 81.82 − 18.18. The payoffs look like:
120 - (1.1)(81.82) = 30
18.18
90 - (1.1)(81.82) = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
26/ 37
Replicating Portfolios
▶ Compare the payoffs of the call option to that of a portfolio consisting of one
share of stock and borrowing $81.82 at the risk-free rate of 10%. The price of
establishing this portfolio is 100 − 81.82 − 18.18. The payoffs look like:
120 - (1.1)(81.82) = 30
18.18
90 - (1.1)(81.82) = 0
▶ Note that these payoffs are the same as the payoffs of 3 call options
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
26/ 37
Replicating Portfolios
▶ Since these two portfolios (the stock plus borrowing at the risk-free rate and the
3 calls) have the same payoffs, the Law of One Price tells us that they must have
the same price
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
27/ 37
Replicating Portfolios
▶ Since these two portfolios (the stock plus borrowing at the risk-free rate and the
3 calls) have the same payoffs, the Law of One Price tells us that they must have
the same price
▶ So we know that it must be the case that
3C = 18.18 =⇒ C = 6.06
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
27/ 37
Replicating Portfolios
▶ Since these two portfolios (the stock plus borrowing at the risk-free rate and the
3 calls) have the same payoffs, the Law of One Price tells us that they must have
the same price
▶ So we know that it must be the case that
3C = 18.18 =⇒ C = 6.06
▶ Suppose C ̸= 6.06. Where is there an arbitrage opportunity?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
27/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Alternative approach: Consider a portfolio consisting of one stock and
writing 3 calls:
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
28/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Alternative approach: Consider a portfolio consisting of one stock and
writing 3 calls:
▶ If the price of the stock in year 1 is $120, then the payoff of the call is $10, so
the payoff of 3 written calls is −$30. Then the payoff of the whole portfolio is
120 − 30 = $90.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
28/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Alternative approach: Consider a portfolio consisting of one stock and
writing 3 calls:
▶ If the price of the stock in year 1 is $120, then the payoff of the call is $10, so
the payoff of 3 written calls is −$30. Then the payoff of the whole portfolio is
120 − 30 = $90.
▶ If the price of the stock in year 1 is $90, then the payoff of the call is $0, so the
payoff of 3 written calls is $0. Then the payoff of the whole portfolio is
90 − 0 = $90.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
28/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Alternative approach: Consider a portfolio consisting of one stock and
writing 3 calls:
▶ If the price of the stock in year 1 is $120, then the payoff of the call is $10, so
the payoff of 3 written calls is −$30. Then the payoff of the whole portfolio is
120 − 30 = $90.
▶ If the price of the stock in year 1 is $90, then the payoff of the call is $0, so the
payoff of 3 written calls is $0. Then the payoff of the whole portfolio is
90 − 0 = $90.
▶ This is a risk-free portfolio!! It pays $90 no matter the state of the world (i.e.,
no matter the final price of the stock).
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
28/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Since this is a risk-free portfolio paying $90 in one year, it must cost
90
= $81.82 today.
(1.10)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
29/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Since this is a risk-free portfolio paying $90 in one year, it must cost
90
= $81.82 today.
(1.10)
▶ Another way to express the price of this portfolio is in terms of the initial stock
price of $100 and the price of call options:
100 − 3C
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
29/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Since this is a risk-free portfolio paying $90 in one year, it must cost
90
= $81.82 today.
(1.10)
▶ Another way to express the price of this portfolio is in terms of the initial stock
price of $100 and the price of call options:
100 − 3C
▶ So we have that
81.82 = 100 − 3C =⇒ C = 6.06
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
29/ 37
Perfect Hedge
▶ Since this is a risk-free portfolio paying $90 in one year, it must cost
90
= $81.82 today.
(1.10)
▶ Another way to express the price of this portfolio is in terms of the initial stock
price of $100 and the price of call options:
100 − 3C
▶ So we have that
81.82 = 100 − 3C =⇒ C = 6.06
▶ This second approach exploits the ability to create a perfect hedge, i.e., use a
portfolio of shares of stock and options to replicate the payoffs of a risk-free bond
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
29/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ How did we come up with the risk-free portfolio of one share of stock and 3
written calls?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
30/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ How did we come up with the risk-free portfolio of one share of stock and 3
written calls?
▶ Definition: The Hedge Ratio is definted as H =
factors by which the stock price evolves.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
Cu −Cd
,
uS0 −dS0
where u and d are the
30/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ How did we come up with the risk-free portfolio of one share of stock and 3
written calls?
▶ Definition: The Hedge Ratio is definted as H =
factors by which the stock price evolves.
Cu −Cd
,
uS0 −dS0
where u and d are the
▶ In our example, d = 0.9 and u = 1.2. Cu and Cd are the call’s payoff in the two
states of the world.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
30/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ How did we come up with the risk-free portfolio of one share of stock and 3
written calls?
▶ Definition: The Hedge Ratio is definted as H =
factors by which the stock price evolves.
Cu −Cd
,
uS0 −dS0
where u and d are the
▶ In our example, d = 0.9 and u = 1.2. Cu and Cd are the call’s payoff in the two
states of the world.
▶ In general, our stock tree looks like:
uS0
S0
dS0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
30/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ And our option tree looks like
Cu
C
Cd
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
31/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ And our option tree looks like
Cu
C
Cd
▶ A portfolio consisting of H shares of stock and one written call will be risk-free.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
31/ 37
Hedge Ratio
▶ And our option tree looks like
Cu
C
Cd
▶ A portfolio consisting of H shares of stock and one written call will be risk-free.
▶ In our example, the hedge ratio was
H=
10 − 0
1
=
120 − 90
3
So that’s how we chose the portfolio of one share of stock and 3 written calls.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
31/ 37
Pricing Procedure
Given S0 , u, d, K , and rf , the pricing procedure is:
1. Calculate S1 in the two states, S1 = uS0 and S1 = dS0 . Calculate the payoffs of
the option in the two states implied by S1 and K .
2. Find the hedge ratio H.
3. Find the payoff of the portfolio composed of H shares of stock and one written
option.
4. Check that this portfolio is risk-free!!
5. Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate.
6. Set the value above equal to HS0 − Poption
7. Solve for Poption
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
32/ 37
Example
Suppose S0 = 50, u = 1.1, d = 0.9, rf = 0.05, and we want to price a call option on
this stock with strike price K = 50. Let’s use our pricing procedure.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
33/ 37
Example
Suppose S0 = 50, u = 1.1, d = 0.9, rf = 0.05, and we want to price a call option on
this stock with strike price K = 50. Let’s use our pricing procedure.
▶ Step 1: Calculate S1 in the two states and the payoffs of the option in the two
states:
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
33/ 37
Example
So our stock price tree looks like:
uS0 = 55
S0 = 50
dS0 = 45
And our option tree looks like
Cu = 5
C
Cd = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
34/ 37
Example
▶ Step 2: Find the hedge ratio H:
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
35/ 37
Example
▶ Step 2: Find the hedge ratio H:
H=
5−0
1
=
55 − 45
2
▶ Step 3: Construct a portfolio of H shares of stock and one written option, and
find the payoffs of this portfolio in the two states:
▶ If the stock price goes up (state u), our payoff is
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
35/ 37
Example
▶ Step 2: Find the hedge ratio H:
H=
5−0
1
=
55 − 45
2
▶ Step 3: Construct a portfolio of H shares of stock and one written option, and
find the payoffs of this portfolio in the two states:
▶ If the stock price goes up (state u), our payoff is
1
55 − 5 = 22.5
2
▶ If the stock price goes down (state d), our payoff is
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
35/ 37
Example
▶ Step 2: Find the hedge ratio H:
H=
5−0
1
=
55 − 45
2
▶ Step 3: Construct a portfolio of H shares of stock and one written option, and
find the payoffs of this portfolio in the two states:
▶ If the stock price goes up (state u), our payoff is
1
55 − 5 = 22.5
2
▶ If the stock price goes down (state d), our payoff is
1
45 − 0 = 22.5
2
▶ Step 4: Check that it’s risk-free! ✓
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
35/ 37
Example
▶ Step 5: Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate. The
present value of a risk-free portfolio paying 22.5 in one period is
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
36/ 37
Example
▶ Step 5: Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate. The
present value of a risk-free portfolio paying 22.5 in one period is
22.5
= 21.43
1.05
▶ Step 6: Set this value equal to HS0 − C :
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
36/ 37
Example
▶ Step 5: Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate. The
present value of a risk-free portfolio paying 22.5 in one period is
22.5
= 21.43
1.05
▶ Step 6: Set this value equal to HS0 − C :
21.43 =
1
50 − C
2
▶ Step 7: Solve for C :
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
36/ 37
Example
▶ Step 5: Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate. The
present value of a risk-free portfolio paying 22.5 in one period is
22.5
= 21.43
1.05
▶ Step 6: Set this value equal to HS0 − C :
21.43 =
1
50 − C
2
▶ Step 7: Solve for C :
C = 25 − 21.43 = 3.57
And we’re done! We’ve priced this option.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
36/ 37
Probabilities/Expected Return
▶ Question: Where did the probabilities that the stock price would go up or down
show up in this model/pricing procedure?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
37/ 37
Probabilities/Expected Return
▶ Question: Where did the probabilities that the stock price would go up or down
show up in this model/pricing procedure?
▶ Answer: They didn’t!
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
37/ 37
Probabilities/Expected Return
▶ Question: Where did the probabilities that the stock price would go up or down
show up in this model/pricing procedure?
▶ Answer: They didn’t!
▶ The probabilities that the stock price increases or decreases don’t matter for
pricing derivatives on the stock!
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
37/ 37
Probabilities/Expected Return
▶ Question: Where did the probabilities that the stock price would go up or down
show up in this model/pricing procedure?
▶ Answer: They didn’t!
▶ The probabilities that the stock price increases or decreases don’t matter for
pricing derivatives on the stock!
▶ The expected return of the stock doesn’t affect the prices of options on the stock
in this model. The prices are derived from a no-arbitrage condition.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
37/ 37
Binomial Model and Option Valuation: Part II
ECO 426: Financial Economics
Monica Tran-Xuan
University at Buffalo
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
1/ 27
Table of Contents
Recap
Two Step Binomial
N-Step Binomial
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
2/ 27
Table of Contents
Recap
Two Step Binomial
N-Step Binomial
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
3/ 27
Recap/Intro
▶ Last time we covered using the Hedge Ratio to construct a perfect hedge
(risk-free portfolio) and price call options in a one step binomial tree
d
▶ Defining H = uSCu −C
, we found that a portfolio consisting of being long H
0 −dS0
shares of stock and short one option was risk-free
▶ Since it was risk-free, we can price it as a bond using the risk-free rate
▶ Today we will extend the binomial model to two steps and see how we can price
derivatives
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
4/ 27
Recap/Intro
Recall our pricing procedure in the one-step model:
1. Calculate S1 in the two states, S1 = uS0 and S1 = dS0 . Calculate the payoffs of
the option in the two states implied by S1 and K .
2. Find the hedge ratio H.
3. Find the payoff of the portfolio composed of H shares of stock and one written
option.
4. Check that this portfolio is risk-free!!
5. Find the present value of this portfolio using the risk-free rate.
6. Set the value above equal to HS0 − Poption
7. Solve for Poption
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
5/ 27
Table of Contents
Recap
Two Step Binomial
N-Step Binomial
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
6/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Model
▶ Suppose now we want to price a call option on a stock that evolves twice before
the expiration of the option, i.e, T = 2
▶ Suppose u = 1.1, d = 0.95, S0 = 100, and rf = 0.05 per period. We want to price
a call option on this stock with strike price K = 110 and maturity T
▶ We want to adjust the pricing procedure to apply in this two-step version
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
7/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Tree
Our stock price tree looks like:
uuS0 = 121
uS0 = 110
S0 = 100
udS0 = duS0 = 104.5
dS0 = 95
ddS0 = 90.25
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
8/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Tree
Our option value will evolve according to:
Cuu = 11
Cu
Cud = Cdu = 0
Pcall
Cd
Cdd = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 27
Tree for Cu
▶ We can solve this problem by splitting into three binomial trees and using our
pricing procedure to solve each one
▶ First, we solve for Cu using the stock price tree
121
110
104.5
▶ And option price tree
11
Cu
0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
10/ 27
Finding Cu
1. uuS0 = 121, udS0 = 104.5; Cuu = 11 when uu occurs and Cud = 0 when ud occurs
Cuu −Cud
11−0
= 121−104.5
= 23
uuS0 −udS0
Construct portfolio of 32 shares of stock
▶ Payoff if uu: ( 2 )(121) − 11 = 69.66
3
▶ Payoff if ud: ( 2 )(104.5) − 0 = 69.66
3
2. Hedge ratio is
3.
and one written call
4. This portfolio is risk-free!
5. The price of this portfolio at time t = 1 (the previous period) is
6. Then we have that 66.35 = HuS0 − Cu =
2
(110)
3
69.66
1.05
= 66.35
− Cu
7. =⇒ Cu = 6.983
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
11/ 27
Tree for Cd
▶ Our second tree is the bottom one, where we need to find Cd . The stock price
tree is
104.5
95
90.25
▶ And option price tree
0
Cd
0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
12/ 27
Finding Cd
We once again use our pricing procedure to find Cd :
1. duS0 = 104.5, ddS0 = 90.25; Cdu = 0 when du occurs and Cdd = 0 when dd occurs
2. The hedge ratio is H =
Cdu −Cdd
duS0 −ddS0
=
0−0
104.5−90.25
=0
3. Construct portfolio of 0 shares of stock and one written call:
▶ Payoff is (0)(104.5) − 0 = 0 when du occurs
▶ Payoff is (0)(90.25) − 0 = 0 when dd occurs
4. This portfolio is risk-free!
5. Price of this portfolio at time t = 1 is
0
1.05
=0
6. Then we have that 0 = HdS0 − Cd = (0)(95) − Cd
7. =⇒ Cd = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 27
Tree for Pcall
▶ Lastly, we plug in Cu and Cd and can solve a one-step binomial tree for Pcall
▶ Stock price tree is
110
S0 = 100
95
▶ And option price tree
Cu = 6.983
Pcall
Cd = 0
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 27
Finding Pcall
Using our pricing procedure one final time:
1. uS0 = 110, dS0 = 95, Cu = 6.983 and Cd = 0
2. The hedge ratio is H =
Cu −Cd
uS0 −dS0
=
6.983−0
110−95
= 0.4655
3. Construct portfolio of 0.4655 shares of stock and one written call:
▶ Payoff is (0.4655)(110) − 6.983 = 44.22 when u occurs
▶ Payoff is (0.4655)(95) − 0 = 44.22 when d occurs
4. This portfolio is risk-free!
5. Price of this portfolio at time t = 0 is
44.22
1.05
= 42.11
6. Then we have that 42.11 = (0.4655)(S0 ) − Pcall = (0.4655)(100) − Pcall
7. =⇒ Pcall = 4.44
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
15/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Model
▶ So far, we have used this model to price call options
▶ Question: Can we use this model to price other derivatives?
▶ Answer: Yes! This model can be used to price any derivative of the asset price
▶ Any asset whose value is a function of the underlying asset price can be priced
this way
▶ Example: Put option
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Model: Put Option
▶ Suppose T = 2, S0 = 100, u = 1.2, d = 0.9, r = 0.05, and we want to price a put
option on this stock with K = 110.
▶ Our stock price tree is
144
120
S0 = 100
108
90
81
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
17/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Model: Put Option
▶ And our option tree is:
Puu = 0
Pu
Pput
Pdu = Pud = 2
Pd
Pdd = 29
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 27
Two-Step Binomial Model: Put Option
▶ Just like with the call, we need to work backward and find Pu and Pd , and then
use those to find Pput
▶ Pricing procedure is exactly the same!
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
19/ 27
Finding Pu
1. uuS0 = 144, udS0 = 108, Puu = 0, Pud = 2
2. Hedge ratio is
H=
Puu − Pud
0−2
=
= −0.055
uuS0 − udS0
144 − 108
▶ Note: Hedge ratio is negative for put option. Why?
3. Construct portfolio of −0.0556 shares of stock and one written put option:
▶ Payoff if uu: (−0.0556)(144) − 0 = −8.00
▶ Payoff if ud: (−0.0556)(108) − 2 = −8.00
4. It’s risk-free!
5. Price at time t = 1 is
−8
(1.05)
= −7.62
6. Then we have is (−0.0556)(120) − Pu = −7.62
7. =⇒ Pu = 0.948
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 27
Finding Pd
1. ddS0 = 81, duS0 = 108, Pdd = 29, Pdu = 2
2. Hedge ratio is
Pdu − Pdd
2 − 29
−27
=
=
= −1
duS0 − ddS0
108 − 81
27
3. Construct portfolio of −1 shares of stock and one written put option:
H=
▶ Payoff if dd: (−1)(81) − 29 = −110
▶ Payoff if du: (−1)(108) − 2 = −110
4. It’s risk-free!
5. Price at time t = 1 is
−110
1.05
= −104.76
6. Then (−1)(90) − Pd = −104.76
7. =⇒ Pd = 14.76
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
21/ 27
Option Tree
Plugging in Pu and Pd to the option tree gives
Puu = 0
Pu = 0.948
Pput
Pdu = Pud = 2
Pd = 14.76
Pdd = 29
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
22/ 27
Finding Pput
1. uS0 = 120, dS0 = 90, Pu = 0.948, Pd = 14.76
2. Hedge ratio is
Pu − Pd
0.948 − 14.76
=
= −0.4604
uS0 − dS0
120 − 90
3. Construct portfolio of −0.4604 shares of stock and one written option:
▶ Payoff if u: (−0.4604)(120) − 0.948 = −56.196
▶ Payoff if d: (−0.4604)(90) − 14.76 = −56.196
4. It’s risk-free!
5. Price at time t = 0 is
−56.196
1.05
= −53.52
6. Then we have that −53.52 = (−0.4604)(100) − Pput
7. =⇒ Pput = 7.48
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
23/ 27
Table of Contents
Recap
Two Step Binomial
N-Step Binomial
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 27
N-Step Binomial
▶ Can we add more steps to this model and still price derivatives?
▶ Yes, but too much to do by hand
▶ For example, 3 step binomial model has 6 one-step trees; 4 step has 10 one-step
trees
▶ But could write computer program to do it
▶ As you add more and more steps, binomial model will approximate
Black-Scholes model for calls and puts (next time)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
25/ 27
N-Step Binomial
▶ Suppose you want to construct a binomial model with N steps for an option
with maturity T (say a year) on a call option with strike price K
▶ Step size is then ∆t = T /N
▶ Given up and down factors u and d, current stock price S0 , and per period
risk-free rate rf
▶ Can also calculate u and d from underlying price volatility σ; then per period
q
)
volatility is σ( T
N
▶ u and d factors are
q
u=e
d =e
σ
−σ
T
N
q
T
N
▶ Want to build algorithm to solve this binomial tree
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
26/ 27
N-Step Binomial
▶ Pricing procedure is the same
▶ Find all final option values at the end of the tree
Cn,N = max{u n d N−n S0 − K , 0}
for a final node that has seen n “up” steps
▶ Work backward using pricing procedure to construct previous nodes
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
27/ 27
Black-Scholes
ECO 426: Financial Economics
Monica Tran-Xuan
University at Buffalo
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
1/ 24
Table of Contents
Introduction
Black-Scholes Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
2/ 24
Table of Contents
Introduction
Black-Scholes Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
3/ 24
Introduction
▶ Binomial model is flexible but can be tedious with many periods
▶ Option pricing formula would be easier to use
▶ In the 70’s, Economists Fischer Black, Myron Scholes, and Robert Merton
developed what is now known as the Black-Scholes formula for call options
▶ Led to a boom in options trading
▶ Idea is exactly the same as the binomial model; continuously hedge the option so
as to eliminate risk
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
4/ 24
Table of Contents
Introduction
Black-Scholes Model
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
5/ 24
Model Assumptions
▶ To derive the formula, some additional assumptions must be made:
▶ The risk-free rate is constant over the life of the option
▶ The stock price volatility is constant over the life of the option
▶ Stock pays no dividends until after the expiration of the option
▶ Stock price process is continuous (i.e., no “Jumps”)
▶ With these assumptions, as ∆t → 0 (time between subperiods in the binomial
tree), the distribution of the stock price at expiration converges to the
lognormal distribution
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
6/ 24
Notation
▶ St is the price of the underlying asset at time t
▶ t is time denoted in years, T is the expiration date of the option (often t = 0 is
right now)
▶ C (St , t) is the price of a European call option with underlying stock price St at
time t
▶ Ex: What is C (ST , T )?
▶ K is the strike price of the option
▶ r is the (annualized) risk-free rate
▶ µ is the (annualized) expected return of the stock
▶ σ is the (annualized) volatility (or standard deviation) of the stock returns
▶ N(·) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function
▶ That is, the probability that a random draw from a standard normal N(0, 1)
distribution is less than x is N(x)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
7/ 24
Standard Normal Distribution
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
8/ 24
Stock Price Process
▶ From the Black-Scholes assumption, the price process for the underlying asset is
what’s known as a geometric Brownian motion:
dS
= µ dt + σ dZ
S
where dZ is a standard Brownian motion (basically, a simple random walk, i.e.,
Zt − Zs ∼ N(0, t − s)
and
E [dZ ] = 0
▶ Stock return has expected return µ and variance σ 2
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
9/ 24
Black-Scholes Equation
The partial differential equation that the Black-Scholes formula solves is
∂C
∂C
1
∂2C
= rC − rS
+ σ2 S 2
∂t
2
∂S 2
∂S
▶ RHS of this equation is equivalent to our risk-free portfolio of long 1 option and
short H = ∂C
shares of stock.
∂S
▶ LHS is the time decay value of the option plus a term representing the convexity
of the derivative value to the underlying value (i.e., option payoff is bounded
below by 0 but can gain a lot of upside with high volatility).
Equation states that the time decay term and the convexity term exactly offset
each other so the result is a risk-free return.
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
10/ 24
Black-Scholes Formula
The Black-Scholes formula for the price of a European call option is
C (St , t) = St N(d1 ) − e −r (T −t) KN(d2 )
where
ln
d1 =
St
K
2
+ r + σ2 (T − t)
p
σ (T − t)
d2 = d1 − σ
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
p
(T − t)
11/ 24
Intuition Behind the Formula
▶ Can view N(d) terms as risk-adjusted probabilities that the call option will
expire in the money
▶ For example, suppose N(d) = 0 (or very close to 0). Looking at the formula on
the previous slide, it’s clear that the options will be worthless, i.e.,
C (St , t) = St N(d1 ) − e −r (T −t) KN(d2 ) =
St (0) − e −r (T −t) K (0) = 0
▶ So if the option will almost certainly expire out of the money, it won’t be worth
anything (or very little)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
12/ 24
Intuition Behind the Formula
▶ Next, suppose N(d) = 1 (or very close to 1). From the formula we see
C (St , t) = St − e −r (T −t) K
▶ So the value of the option if it will almost certainly expire in the money is the
stock price minus the present value of the strike price
▶ For middle values of N(d) between 0 and 1, formula can be viewed as the
present value of the call’s payoff adjusted for the probability that the option will
expire in the money
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
13/ 24
Intuition Behind the Formula
▶ Why are these N terms risk-adjusted probabilities? Key term is ln SKt , which is
roughly the percentage by which the option is in or out of the money
▶ Example: Suppose stock price St = 105, and strike price K = 100
▶ This option is 5% in the money, and ln SKt = 0.049
▶ Other terms adjust for volatility in remaining time to expiration and the return
on a risk-free investment
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
14/ 24
Black-Scholes for Put Options
▶ Black-Scholes is easily extended to European put option using put-call parity:
P(St , t) = e −r (T −t) K − St + C (St , t)
= e −r (T −t) K (1 − N(d2 )) − St (1 − N(d1 ))
= e −r (T −t) KN(−d2 ) − St N(−d1 )
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
15/ 24
Example
Suppose you want to value a call option with
▶ S0 = 100
▶ K = 95
▶ r = 0.10 (10% per year)
▶ T = 0.25 (3 months or one-quarter of a year)
▶ Since t = 0 here, T − t (time to expiration) is also 0.25
▶ σ = 0.50 (std dev of 50% per year)
It’s pretty straightforward to apply Black-Scholes
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
16/ 24
Example
First calculate:
d1 =
ln(100/95) + (0.10 + (0.52 )/2)(0.25)
√
= 0.43
(0.5) 0.25
√
d2 = 0.43 − (0.5) 0.25 = 0.18
Next find N(d1 ) and N(d2 ), using either a z-score table or computer
(NORM.S.DIST(·,True) in Excel 2010).
Here we have
N(0.43) = 0.6664
N(0.18) = 0.5714
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
17/ 24
Example
Thus the value of the call option is
C = 100(0.6664) − e −(0.10)(0.25) (95)(0.5714)
= 66.64 − 52.94 = 13.70
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
18/ 24
Using Black-Scholes
▶ Suppose you find what appears to be a mispriced option, is there any reason not
to bet heavily on it?
▶ Yes
▶ Do the assumptions of the model hold?
▶ Are my parameter estimates accurate?
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
19/ 24
Are My Parameters Right?
▶ Most are simply directly observable (i.e., current stock price, strike price, time
to maturity)
▶ EXCEPT volatility, which is harder to estimate
▶ Volatility must be estimated from historical data or model
▶ Inaccurate volatility estimate means there could always be a discrepancy
between an option’s price and the Black-Scholes estimate
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
20/ 24
Using Black-Scholes to Estimate Volatility
▶ Instead of using Black-Scholes to price options, can observe the option price in
the market and use the Black-Scholes formula to back out what the “implied”
volatility of the stock return is
▶ Example: CBOE’s VIX index
▶ Also can look at implied volatility of options on the same stock
▶ Find interesting results: volatility smile
▶ Deep out of the money put options have much higher implied volatility than at the
money put options on the same stock
▶ What does this imply about stock price process? Probably includes jumps!
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
21/ 24
Implied Volatility of S&P 500
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
22/ 24
The Greeks
▶ “The Greeks” are partial derivatives of the Black-Scholes formula
▶ They measure the sensitivity of the option value to changes in various parameter
values while holding the other parameters fixed
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
23/ 24
The Greeks
▶ Delta is the sensitivity of the option value to changes in the underlying stock
price:
▶ This is the same as the Hedge Ratio!
H=
Cu − Cd
uS0 − dS0
▶ Positive for calls and negative for puts
▶ Gamma is the sensitivity of Delta to changes in the stock price
▶ Vega is the sensitivity of the option value to changes in the underlying volatility
▶ Theta is the sensitivity of the option value to the passage of time, the “time
decay” of the option
▶ Rho is the sensitivity of the option value to changes in interest rates (usually
small)
Monica Tran-Xuan (UB) Financial Economics
24/ 24
Purchase answer to see full
attachment