Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
https://www.pearson.com/mylab
Course ID: chakroun54908
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
Chapter 1
Introduction: What Is
Economics?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Chapter Outline
1.1 What Is Economics?
1.2 The three economic questions: What, How and Who?
1.3 The Economic Way of Thinking
1.4 Microeconomics Verus Macroeconomics
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1.1 What Is Economics?
Economics: The study of choices when there is scarcity.
Scarcity: The resources we use to produce goods and
services are limited.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Some Examples of Scarcity and Tradeoffs
• You have a limited amount of time. Each hour on the job
means one less hour for study or play.
• A city has a limited amount of land. If the city uses an acre
of land for a park, it has one less acre for housing, retailers,
or industry.
• You have limited income this year. If you spend $17 on a
music CD, that’s $17 less you have to spend on other
products or to save.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Five Factors of Production (1 of 2)
Factors of Production: The resources used to produce
goods and services; also known as production inputs or
resources.
Natural Resources: Resources provided by nature and
used to produce goods and services.
Labor: Human effort, including both physical and mental,
used to produce goods and services.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Five Factors of Production (2 of 2)
Physical Capital: The stock of equipment, machines,
structures, and infrastructure that is used to produce goods
and services.
Human Capital: The knowledge and skills acquired by a
worker through education and experience and used to
produce goods and services.
Entrepreneurship: The effort used to coordinate the factors
of production—natural resources, labor, physical capital, and
human capital—to produce and sell products.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1.2 The Three Key Economic
Questions: What, How, and Who?
The choices made by individuals, firms, and governments
answer three questions:
1. What products do we produce?
2. How do we produce the products?
3. Who consumes the products?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Economic Models
Economists use economic models to explore the choices
people make and the consequences of those choices.
Economic model: A simplified representation of an
economic environment, often employing a graph.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Positive versus Normative Analysis
Most modern economics is based on positive analysis:
Positive Analysis: Answers the question “What is?” or
“What will be?”
A second type of economic reasoning is normative in
nature:
Normative Analysis: Answers the question “What ought
to be?”
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 1.1 Comparing Positive and
Normative Questions
Positive Questions
Normative Questions
• If the government increases the
minimum wage, how many workers
will lose their jobs?
• Should the government
increase the minimum wage?
• If two office-supply firms merge, will
the price of office supplies increase?
• Should the government block
the merger of two office-supply
firms?
• How does a college education affect • Should the government
a person’s productivity and earnings?
subsidize a college education?
• How do consumers respond to a cut
in income taxes?
• Should the government cut
taxes to stimulate the
economy?
• If a nation restricts shoe imports, who • Should the government restrict
benefits and who bears the cost?
imports?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1.3 The Economic Way of Thinking
List the four elements of the economic way of thinking.
“The theory of economics does not furnish a body of settled
conclusions immediately applicable to policy. It is a method
rather than a doctrine, an apparatus of the mind, a technique
of thinking which helps its possessor draw correct
conclusions.”
John Maynard Keynes, The Collected Writings of John
Maynard Keynes, Volume 7
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Use Assumptions to Simplify
Economists use assumptions to make things simpler and
focus attention on what really matters.
We have to be careful to make the right assumptions and
simplifications.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Isolate Variables—Ceteris Paribus
Economists often consider how one variable changes in
isolation, in order to see how its changes affect other
variables.
Variable: A measure of something that can take on
different values.
Ceteris Paribus: The Latin expression meaning that other
variables are held fixed.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Think at the Margin
How will a small change in one variable affect another
variable, and what impact will that have on people’s
decision-making?
Marginal Change: A small, one-unit change in value
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Rational People Respond to Incentives
A key assumption of most economic analysis is that people
act rationally, that is, in their own self-interest.
This does not mean that people are only motivated by selfinterest, but instead that this is their primary motivation.
Rationality implies that when the payoff (benefit) to doing
something changes, people will change their behavior to
make their payoff as large as possible.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1.4 Microeconomics Vs Macroeconomics
The field of economics is divided into two categories:
macroeconomics and microeconomics.
Macroeconomics: The study of the nation’s economy as a
whole; focuses on the issues of inflation, unemployment, and
economic growth.
Microeconomics: The study of the choices made by
households, firms, and governments, and how these choices
affect the markets for goods and services.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Macroeconomics to Understand
Why Economies Grow
The world economy has been growing in recent decades,
averaging about 1.5 percent higher per capita income per
year.
Why do some countries grow much faster than others?
Macroeconomics will help us understand why.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Macroeconomics to Understand
Economic Fluctuations
All countries, even those where per capita income is
generally rising, experience economic fluctuations,
including periods where the economy temporarily shrinks.
What options do governments have to moderate these
fluctuations?
And should they do so?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Macroeconomics to Make
Informed Business Decisions
A manager who studies macroeconomics will be better
equipped to understand the complexities of interest rates
and inflation, and how they affect the firm.
Should a firm borrow money now at a fixed interest rate?
Or wait a while, hoping interest rates will fall?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Microeconomics to Understand
Markets and Predict Changes
One reason for studying microeconomics is to better
understand how markets work and to predict how various
events affect the prices and quantities of products in
markets.
For example, how would a tax on beer affect:
1. The price of beer?
2. How many people buy beer?
3. How many people are likely to drink and drive?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Microeconomics to Make
Personal and Managerial Decisions
On the personal level, we use economic analysis to decide
how to spend our time, what career to pursue, and how to
spend and save the money we earn.
Managers use economic analysis to decide how to produce
goods and services, how much to produce, and how much to
charge for them.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Microeconomics to Evaluate
Public Policies
We can use economic analysis to determine how well the
government performs its roles in the market economy.
For example, prescription drugs are protected from being
copied because of government patents.
If we shortened patent lengths, we may get cheaper generic
drugs sooner; but fewer drugs may get developed because
of the decreased profitability of drug development.
Microeconomics can help evaluate the best policy here.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Key Terms
Ceteris paribus
Marginal change
Economic model
Microeconomics
Economics
Natural resources
Entrepreneurship
Normative analysis
Factors of production
Physical capital
Human capital
Positive analysis
Labor
Scarcity
Macroeconomics
Variable
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1A.1 Using Graphs
Economists use several types of graphs to present data,
represent relationships between variables, and explain
concepts.
Although it is possible to do economics without graphs, it’s
a lot easier with them in your toolbox.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.1 Graphs of Single Variables
Left: Pie Graph for Types of Recorded Music Sold in the United States
Right: Bar Graph for U.S. Export Sales of Copyrighted Products
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.2 Time Series Graph
A time series graph shows how the value of a variable changes
over time. In the right panel, the vertical axis is truncated,
indicated by the double hash marks on the y-axis. This
exaggerates the fluctuations in the data.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.3 Basic Elements of a TwoVariable Graph
One variable is measured along
the horizontal, or x, axis, while
the other variable is measured
along the vertical, or y, axis.
The origin is defined as the
intersection of the two axes,
where the values of both
variables are zero.
The dashed lines show the
values of the two variables at a
particular point.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Graphing Two Variables
The slope of a line relating two variables on a graph indicates
whether they have a positive or negative relationship.
Positive relationship: A relationship in which two variables
move in the same direction.
Negative relationship: A relationship in which two variables
move in opposite directions.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.4 Relationship between
Hours Worked and Income
There is a positive
relationship between work
hours and income, so the
income curve is positively
sloped.
The slope of the curve is
$8: Each additional hour of
work increases income by
$8.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Computing the Slope
Slope
Income
Work hours
Vertical difference between two points rise
Slope
Horizontal difference between two points run
Slope of a curve: The vertical difference between two points (the rise)
divided by the horizontal difference (the run).
In general, if the variable on the vertical axis is y and the variable on the
horizontal axis is x, we can express the slope as:
Slope
y
x
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.5 Movement Along a Curve
versus Shifting the Curve
To draw a curve showing the
relationship between hours worked
and income, we fix the weekly
allowance ($40) and the wage ($8
per hour).
A change in the hours worked
causes movement along the curve,
for example, from point b to point c.
A change in any other variable shifts
the entire curve. For example, a $50
increase in the allowance (to $90)
shifts the entire curve upward by
$50.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.6 Negative Relationship between
CD Purchases and Downloaded Songs
There is a negative relationship between
the number of CDs and downloaded
songs that a consumer can afford with a
budget of $360.
The slope of the curve is −$12: Each
additional CD (at a price of $12 each)
decreases the number of downloadable
songs (at $1 each) by 12 songs.
Slope
Vertical difference
Horizontal difference
120 240 120
12
20 10
10
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.7 Nonlinear Relationships (1 of 2)
There is a positive and nonlinear
relationship between study time
and the grade on an exam. As
study time increases, the exam
grade increases at a decreasing
rate.
For example, the second hour of
study increased the grade by 4
points (from 6 points to 10 points),
but the ninth hour of study
increases the grade by only 1 point
(from 24 points to 25 points).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 1A.7 Nonlinear Relationships (2 of 2)
There is a positive and nonlinear
relationship between the quantity of
grain produced and total production
cost. As the quantity increases, the
total cost increases at an increasing
rate.
For example, to increase production
from 1 ton to 2 tons, production cost
increases by $5 (from $10 to $15) but
to increase the production from 10 to
11 tons, total cost increases by $25
(from $100 to $125).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
1A.2 Computing Percentage Changes
and Using Equations
To compute a percentage change, we divide the change in
the variable by the initial value of the variable, and then
multiply by 100:
New value initial value
Percentage change
100
Initial value
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 3: The Perils of
Percentages (1 of 2)
In the 1970s, the government of Mexico City repainted the
highway lane lines on the Viaducto to transform a four-lane
highway into a six-lane highway.
• The government announced that the highway capacity had
increased by 50% (equal to 2 divided by 4).
• Unfortunately, the number of collisions and traffic fatalities
increased, and one year later the government restored the
four-lane highway and announced that the capacity had
decreased by 33% (equal to 2 divided by 6).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 3: The Perils of
Percentages (2 of 2)
This anecdote reveals a potential problem with using the
simple approach to compute percentage changes. Because
the initial value (the denominator) changes, the computation
of percentage increases and decreases are not symmetric.
There is a solution to this problem: using the midpoint
method for percentage changes:
Percentage change
New value initial value
100
Average value
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Equations to Compute Missing
Values (1 of 2)
It will often be useful to compute the value of the numerator
or the denominator of an equation. For example, if we know
the change in work hours, and the slope of the line relating
change in income and change in work hours:
Income
Slope
Work hours
Work hours Slope Income
Income Work hours Slope
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Equations to Compute Missing
Values (2 of 2)
Income Work hours Slope
Then, if you work seven extra hours, and the slope of this
line is $8 per hour, then your change in income is:
Income 7 hours $8per hour
Income $56
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Key Terms (Appendix)
Negative relationship
Positive relationship
Slope of a curve
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is
provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their
courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of
any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will
destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work
and materials from it should never be made available to students
except by instructors using the accompanying text in their
classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these
restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and
the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
Chapter 2
The Key Principles of
Economics
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Chapter Outline
2.1 The Principle of Opportunity Cost
2.2 The Marginal Principle
2.3 The Principle of Voluntary Exchange
2.4 The Principle of Diminishing Returns
2.5 The Real-Nominal Principle
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
2.1 The Principle of Opportunity Cost
Apply the principle of opportunity cost.
Economics is all about making choices; to make good
choices, we must compare the benefit of something to its
cost.
Opportunity Cost: What you sacrifice to get something.
“There is no such thing as a free lunch”
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 1: The cost of doing business
Jack left a job paying $60,000 per year to
start his own florist shop in a building he
owns. The market value of the building
is $80,000. He pays $30,000 per year for
flowers and other supplies, and has a bank
account that pays 5 percent interest. What is
the economic cost of Jack's business?
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Cost of Military Spending
The war in Iraq cost the United States an estimated $1
trillion. Each $100 billion could:
• Enroll 13 million preschool children in the Head Start
program for one year.
• Hire 1.8 million additional teachers for one year.
• Immunize all the children in less-developed countries for
the next 33 years.
The true cost of the war was its opportunity cost: what the
United States sacrificed for it.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 2.1 Scarcity and the Production
Possibilities Curve (1 of 3)
Production possibilities
curve: A curve that shows
the possible combinations
of products that an
economy can produce,
given that its productive
resources are fully
employed and efficiently
used.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 2.1 Scarcity and the Production
Possibilities Curve (2 of 3)
The production
possibilities curve
illustrates the principle of
opportunity cost for an
entire economy.
An economy has a fixed
amount of resources. If
these resources are fully
employed, an increase in
the production of wheat
comes at the expense of
steel.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 2.1 Scarcity and the Production
Possibilities Curve (3 of 3)
Each additional 10 tons of
wheat requires sacrificing
progressively more steel—
50 tons from a to b, 180
tons from c to d.
Some resources are better
suited for steel production,
and some are better suited
to wheat production.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 2.2 Shifting the Production
Possibilities Curve
An increase in the quantity
of resources or
technological innovation in
an economy shifts the
production possibilities
curve outward.
Starting from point f, a
nation could produce more
steel (point g), more wheat
(point h), or more of both
goods (points between g
and h).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
2.2 The Marginal Principle
Apply the marginal principle.
We rarely make all-or-nothing choices. Economists tend to think
in marginal terms: the effect of a small or incremental change.
Marginal benefit: The additional benefit resulting from a small
increase in some activity.
Marginal cost: The additional cost resulting from a small
increase in some activity.
The marginal principle: Increase the level of an activity as long
as its marginal benefit exceeds its marginal cost. Choose the
level at which the marginal benefit equals the marginal cost.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 2: Hiring people
1) The table below shows the marginal benefit that Khaled earns from keeping his store
open one more hour. Khaled has a marginal cost of $40 per hour. Khaled stays open
20 hours.
a) Do you think Khaled’s decision to stay open 20 hours is optimal? Why? (1 mark)
b) How many hours do you advise Khaled to stay open? Why? (2 marks)
2.3 The Principle of Voluntary Exchange
Apply the principle of voluntary exchange.
Why would two people trade with one another?
Because each believes that what they receive is worth
more to them than what they give.
The principle of voluntary exchange: A voluntary
exchange between two people makes both better off.
Example: When you work, you trade your time for money.
The money is more valuable than the time to you, and your
time is more valuable than the money to your employer.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
2.4 The Principle of Diminishing
Returns
Apply the principle of diminishing returns.
You run a small copy shop with one copying machine and
one worker, who can copy 500 pages per hour.
You add another worker, but output increases to only 800
pages per hour, not doubling to 1,000.
Why? They now share the copier, so each is less productive.
The principle of diminishing returns: Suppose output is
produced with two or more inputs, and we increase one input
while holding the other input or inputs fixed. Beyond some
point—called the point of diminishing returns—output will
increase at a decreasing rate.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Why Do Diminishing Returns Occur?
Diminishing returns occurs because one of the inputs to the
production process is fixed.
When a firm can vary all its inputs, including the size of the
production facility, the principle of diminishing returns is not
relevant.
If you doubled both the number of workers and equipment,
output ought to double also—or maybe more than double, if
specialization is beneficial.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 4: Fertilizer and Crop Yields
Adding fertilizer to a field
increases its production; but
this is subject to diminishing
returns.
Why? The other inputs to the
production process are fixed,
such as the field itself, the rain,
the sunlight, etc. Each
additional bag of fertilizer is
progressively less productive.
Some representative numbers
are on the next slide.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 2.1 Fertilizer and Corn Yield
Bags of Nitrogen Fertilizer
Bushels of Corn per Acre
0
85
1
120
2
135
3
144
4
147
The first bag of fertilizer increases production by 35
bushels, but subsequent bags of fertilizer increase
production by less and less.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
2.5 The Real-Nominal Principle
Apply the real-nominal principle.
Most modern money is not inherently valuable, but is
valuable because of what it will buy.
The real-nominal principle: What matters to people is the
real value of money or income—its purchasing power—not
its face value.
Nominal value: The face value of an amount of money.
Real value: The value of an amount of money in terms of
what it can buy.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 2.2 The Real Value of the
Minimum Wage, 1974–2015
Blank
1974
2015
Minimum wage per hour
$2.00
$7.25
Weekly income from minimum wage
80
290
Cost of a standard basket of goods
47
236
1.70
1.23
Number of baskets per week
Between 1974 and 2015, the federal minimum wage increased
from $2.00 to $7.25.
Was the typical minimum-wage worker better or worse off in
2015?
We can apply the real-nominal principle to see that the value of
the minimum wage has actually decreased over this time period.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 5: Repaying Student Loans
Suppose you finish college with $40,000 in student loans and
start a job that pays a salary of $50,000 in the first year. In 10
years, you must repay your college loans. Which would you
prefer, stable prices, rising prices, or falling prices?
Hint: The nominal value of the loans will not change, even as
prices change.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Key Terms
Marginal benefit
Marginal cost
Opportunity cost
Production possibilities curve
Nominal value
Real value
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is
provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their
courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of
any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will
destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work
and materials from it should never be made available to students
except by instructors using the accompanying text in their
classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these
restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and
the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
Chapter 3
Demand, Supply, and
Market Equilibrium
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Chapter Outline
3.1 The Demand Curve
3.2 The Supply Curve
3.3 Market Equilibrium: Bringing Demand and Supply
Together
3.4 Market Effects of Changes in Demand
3.5 Market Effects of Changes in Supply
3.6 Predicting and Explaining Market Changes
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 The Demand Curve
Describe and explain the law of demand.
In this chapter, we will develop the model of demand and
supply—the most important tool of economic analysis.
We will assume markets are perfectly competitive,
implying that individual sellers are so small they cannot
affect the market price.
Perfectly competitive market: A market with many buyers
and sellers of a homogeneous product and no barriers to
entry.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Consumers and Demand
How much of a particular product are consumers willing to
buy during a particular period? We call this the quantity
demanded.
Quantity demanded: The amount of a product that
consumers are willing and able to buy.
What alters the amount consumers are willing to buy? We
divide this into two categories:
• The price of the product
• Everything else!
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.1 The Individual Demand
Curve (1 of 4)
The table shows how
many pizzas a consumer
will buy at a selection of
prices. This is a demand
schedule.
Demand schedule: A
table that shows the
relationship between the
price of a product and the
quantity demanded,
ceteris paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.1 The Individual Demand
Curve (2 of 4)
We plot each of the pricequantity pairs on the graph;
joining those points gives
the individual demand
curve for pizza.
Individual demand curve:
A curve that shows the
relationship between the
price of a good and quantity
demanded by an individual
consumer, ceteris paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.1 The Individual Demand
Curve (3 of 4)
The demand curve slopes
downward; this is so typical,
we call it the law of demand.
Law of demand: There is a
negative relationship between
price and quantity demanded,
ceteris paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.1 The Individual Demand
Curve (4 of 4)
As price rises from $8 to $10,
the consumer buys 3 fewer
pizzas. This is a change in
quantity demanded.
Change in quantity
demanded: A change in the
quantity consumers are willing
and able to buy when the price
changes; represented
graphically by movement along
the demand curve.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.2 From Individual to Market
Demand
Adding quantity demanded by each consumer at each price
gives us the market demand curve.
Market demand curve: A curve showing the relationship
between price and quantity demanded by all consumers,
ceteris paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 1: Young Smokers and the
Law of Demand
As price decreases, the quantity of
cigarettes demanded increases for
two reasons:
• People who already smoke,
choose to smoke more; and
• Some (mostly young) people start
smoking.
Keeping cigarette prices high, or
increasing them with taxes, is one way
that governments try to discourage
young people from starting smoking.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.2 The Supply Curve
Describe and explain the law of supply.
How much of a particular product are firms willing to produce
and sell during a particular period? We call this the quantity
supplied.
Quantity supplied: The amount of a product that firms are
willing and able to sell.
What alters the amount firms are willing to sell? We divide this
into two categories:
• The price of the product
• Everything else!
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.3 The Individual Supply
Curve (1 of 4)
The table shows how many
pizzas a firm will sell at a
selection of prices. This is a
supply schedule.
Supply schedule: A table
that shows the relationship
between the price of a
product and the quantity
supplied, ceteris paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.3 The Individual Supply
Curve (2 of 4)
We plot each of the pricequantity pairs on the graph;
joining those points gives the
individual supply curve for
pizza.
Individual demand curve: A
curve that shows the
relationship between the price
of a good and quantity supplied
by an individual firm, ceteris
paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.3 The Individual Supply
Curve (3 of 4)
The supply curve slopes upward; this
is so typical, we call it the law of
supply.
Law of supply: There is a positive
relationship between price and
quantity supplied, ceteris paribus.
There are some prices below which
the firm would not provide any pizzas;
for this firm, the minimum supply
price appears to be $2.
Minimum supply price: The lowest
price at which a product will be
supplied.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.3 The Individual Supply
Curve (4 of 4)
As price rises from $8 to $10,
the firm is willing to provide 100
more pizzas. This is a change
in quantity supplied.
Change in quantity supplied:
A change in the quantity firms
are willing and able to sell when
the price changes; represented
graphically by movement along
the supply curve.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Why Is the Individual Supply Curve
Positively Sloped?
A higher price encourages the firm to increase its output by
purchasing more materials and hiring more workers.
Even if the new materials are more expensive, or the new
workers are more costly or less productive, the firm is willing to
incur those higher marginal costs to sell at higher prices.
• This is consistent with the marginal principle: increase the
level of an activity as long as its marginal benefit exceeds its
marginal cost. Choose the level at which the marginal benefit
equals the marginal cost.
The price is the marginal benefit; the supply curve shows the
firm’s marginal cost of production.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.4 From Individual to Market
Supply
Adding quantity supplied by each firm at each price gives
us the market supply curve.
Market supply curve: A curve showing the relationship
between price and quantity supplied by all firms, ceteris
paribus.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.5 The Market Supply Curve
with Many Firms
A perfectly competitive
market has hundreds of
firms rather than just two.
In the case of many firms,
the market supply curve
will be smooth rather than
kinked.
In this graph, we assume
there are 100 firms
identical to Lola’s.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Why Is the Market Supply Curve
Positively Sloped?
There are two reasons why the market supply curve is
positively sloped. As the market price increases,
1. Individual firms increase output by purchasing more
materials and hiring more workers; and
2. New firms enter the market, encouraged by the higher
price.
As with the individual supply curve, the market supply curve
shows the marginal cost of production, this time for the
market as a whole.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 2: Sheep, Wool, and the
Law of Supply
In the 1990s, the world
price of wool decreased
by about 30%. The law
of supply suggests wool
output would decrease.
It did; wool-exporting
countries like New
Zealand converted land
to more profitable uses,
like dairy farming,
forestry, and wine
production.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.3 Market Equilibrium: Bringing
Demand and Supply Together
Explain the role of price in reaching a market
equilibrium.
A market is an arrangement that brings buyers and sellers
together. These buyers and sellers jointly determine prices
and quantities traded.
Market equilibrium: A situation in which the quantity
demanded equals the quantity supplied at the prevailing
market price.
When a market is in equilibrium, there is no pressure on the
price to change.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.6 Market Equilibrium (1 of 3)
At the market equilibrium
(point a, with price = $8 and
quantity = 30,000), the
quantity supplied equals the
quantity demanded.
Everyone willing to pay $8
receives a pizza for that
price; and every pizza firms
are willing to produce at $8
gets sold.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.6 Market Equilibrium (2 of 3)
At a price below the equilibrium
price ($6), there is excess
demand—the quantity demanded
at point c exceeds the quantity
supplied at point b.
Excess demand: A situation in
which, at the prevailing price, the
quantity demanded exceeds the
quantity supplied.
This mismatch causes the price of
pizza to rise; firms will realize they
can raise the price and still sell all
the pizzas they planned to sell.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.6 Market Equilibrium (3 of 3)
At a price above the equilibrium price
($12), there is excess supply—the
quantity supplied at point e exceeds
the quantity demanded at point d.
Excess supply: A situation in which
the quantity supplied exceeds the
quantity demanded at the prevailing
price.
This mismatch causes the price of
pizza to fall; firms will realize they
cannot sell all of their pizzas at the
prevailing price, and will start
undercutting one another.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 3: Shrinking Wine Lakes
The European Union guarantees
minimum prices for agricultural
products like grapes. These
above-equilibrium prices
encourage overproduction, which
the EU guarantees to buy.
Recent reforms have reduced
(and in some cases eliminated)
these price guarantees, resulting
in shrinking excess “wine lakes”
and “butter mountains.”
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.4 Market Effects of Changes in
Demand
Describe the effect of a change in demand on the
equilibrium price.
Market equilibrium occurs when the quantity supplied equals
the quantity demanded.
Changes in the demand side of the market can affect the
equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.7 Change in Quantity Demanded
Versus Change in Demand (1 of 2)
Panel (A) shows a change in price causing a change in quantity
demanded, a movement along a single demand curve.
A decrease in price causes a move from point a to point b, increasing
the quantity demanded.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.7 Change in Quantity Demanded
Versus Change in Demand (2 of 2)
Panel (B) shows a change in demand caused by changes in a variable
other than the price. This shifts the entire demand curve.
An increase in demand shifts the demand curve from D1 to D2.
Change in demand: A shift of the demand curve caused by a change in
a variable other than the price of the product.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Increases in Demand Shift the Demand
Curve (1 of 3)
What could cause the demand curve to increase (shift to the
right)? Anything other than a price decrease that makes
consumers want to buy more of the good. Some examples:
• An income change: Consumers buy more vacations and
new cars when their income increases. We call these
normal goods. But consumers buy less of some goods (like
second-hand clothing, or ramen noodle packets) when their
income increases: these are inferior goods.
Normal good: A good for which an increase in income
increases demand.
Inferior good: A good for which an increase in income
decreases demand.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Increases in Demand Shift the Demand
Curve (2 of 3)
More examples:
• Increase in the price of a substitute good: Tacos and pizza are
substitutes: when the price of tacos rise, some consumers switch
to buying pizzas instead.
• Decrease in the price of a complementary good: Pay-per-view
sports events and pizza are complements: when the price of a
pay-per-view event falls, more consumers watch it, and buy more
pizza to consume with it.
Substitutes: Two goods for which an increase in the price of one
good increases the demand for the other good.
Complements: Two goods for which a decrease in the price of
one good increases the demand for the other good.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Increases in Demand Shift the Demand
Curve (3 of 3)
Even more examples:
• Increase in population: More people means more
potential pizza consumers.
• Shift in consumer preferences: Consumers might
decide the like for pizza more than they used to. A
successful pizza advertising campaign might increase
the demand for pizza.
• Expectations of higher future prices: If consumers
learn pizza prices will rise next week, they might buy
more pizzas this week, and fewer next week.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.1 Increases in Demand Shift
the Demand Curve to the Right
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.8 An Increase in Demand
Increases the Equilibrium Price (1 of 2)
An increase in demand shifts
the demand curve to the right:
At each price, the quantity
demanded increases.
At the initial price ($8), there is
excess demand, with the
quantity demanded (point b)
exceeding the quantity
supplied (point a).
The excess demand causes
the price to rise, and
equilibrium is restored at point
c.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.8 An Increase in Demand
Increases the Equilibrium Price (2 of 2)
The result of the increase
in demand: the equilibrium
price rises to $10, and the
equilibrium quantity of
pizzas rises to 40,000
pizzas per month.
Generally, we predict an
increase in demand will
increase the equilibrium
price and increase the
equilibrium quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.2 Decreases in Demand Shift
the Demand Curve to the Left
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.9 A Decrease in Demand
Decreases the Equilibrium Price (1 of 2)
A decrease in demand shifts the
demand curve to the left: At each
price, the quantity demanded
decreases.
At the initial price ($8), there is
excess supply, with the quantity
supplied (point a) exceeding the
quantity demanded (point b).
The excess supply causes the
price to drop, and equilibrium is
restored at point c.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.9 A Decrease in Demand
Decreases the Equilibrium Price (2 of 2)
The result of the decrease in
demand: the equilibrium price
falls to $6, and the equilibrium
quantity of pizzas falls to
20,000 pizzas per month.
Generally, we predict an
decrease in demand will
decrease the equilibrium price
and decrease the equilibrium
quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 4: Craft Beer and the Price
of Hops
Between 2012 and 2017,
U.S. craft beer production
increased more than 30%.
Craft beer brewers
increased their demand for
ingredients, including hops.
As a result of the demand
increase, the equilibrium
price of hops rose
substantially: from $3.17 to
$5.92 per pound.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.5 Market Effects of Changes in Supply
Describe the effect of a change in supply on the
equilibrium price.
Market equilibrium occurs when the quantity supplied equals
the quantity demanded.
Changes in the supply side of the market can affect the
equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.10 Change in Quantity
Supplied versus Change in Supply (1 of 2)
Panel (A) shows a change in price causing a change in quantity
supplied, a movement along a single supply curve.
An increase in price causes a move from point a to point b,
increasing the quantity supplied.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.10 Change in Quantity
Supplied versus Change in Supply (2 of 2)
Panel (B) shows a change in supply caused by changes in a variable
other than price. This shifts the entire supply curve.
An increase in supply shifts the entire supply curve from S1 to S2.
Change in supply: A shift of the supply curve caused by a change in a
variable other than the price of the product.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Increases in Supply Shift the Supply
Curve
What could cause the supply curve to increase (shift to the right)?
Anything other than a price increase that makes firms want to provide
more of the good. Some examples:
• A decrease in input costs: If wages or the cost of materials go down,
production becomes more profitable, so firms expand.
• Technological advance: New technologies can make production more
profitable and hence encourage expansion.
• Government subsidy: A payment from the government will also make
production more profitable also.
• Expected future prices falling: A firm that learns prices will fall next
month will try to sell more at current higher prices.
• Number of producers: More firms mean more production.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.3 Changes in Supply Shift the
Supply Curve Downward and to the Right
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.11 An Increase in Supply
Decreases the Equilibrium Price (1 of 2)
An increase in supply shifts
the supply curve to the right:
At each price, the quantity
supplied increases.
At the initial price ($8), there
is excess supply, with the
quantity supplied (point b)
exceeding the quantity
demanded (point a). The
excess supply causes the
price to drop, and equilibrium
is restored at point c.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.11 An Increase in Supply
Decreases the Equilibrium Price (2 of 2)
The result of the increase in
supply: the equilibrium price
falls to $6, and the equilibrium
quantity of pizzas rises to
36,000 pizzas per month.
Generally, we predict an
increase in supply will
decrease the equilibrium price
and increase the equilibrium
quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.4 Changes in Supply Shift the
Supply Curve Upward and to the Left
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.12 A Decrease in Supply
Increases the Equilibrium Price (1 of 2)
A decrease in supply shifts
the supply curve to the left.
At each price, the quantity
supplied decreases.
At the initial price ($8), there
is excess demand, with the
quantity demanded (point a)
exceeding the quantity
supplied (point b). The
excess demand causes the
price to rise, and equilibrium
is restored at point c.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.12 A Decrease in Supply
Increases the Equilibrium Price (2 of 2)
The result of the decrease in
supply: the equilibrium price
rises to $10, and the
equilibrium quantity of pizzas
rises to 24,000 pizzas per
month.
Generally, we predict a
decrease in supply will
increase the equilibrium price
and decrease the equilibrium
quantity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Simultaneous Changes in Demand and
Supply
What happens to the equilibrium price and quantity when
both demand and supply increase?
It depends on which change is larger.
• If the effect on demand is larger, then the overall change
will “look like” the change in demand.
• If the effect on supply is larger, then the overall change
will “look like” the change in supply.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 3.13 Market Effects of Simultaneous
Changes in Demand and Supply
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 5: The Harmattan and the
Price of Chocolate
The harmattan is a dry, dusty
wind from the Sahara desert.
Each year it sweeps through
cocoa plantations in Ghana and
Ivory Coast, drying coca pods
and decreasing yields.
In 2015, the harmattan was
longer than usual (14 days rather
than the usual 5 days) so crop
yields were lower than usual; the
decrease in supply caused world
cocoa prices to rise in 2015.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
3.6 Predicting and Explaining Market
Changes
Use information on price and quantity to determine what
caused a change in price.
Using our demand and supply model, we have shown how
equilibrium prices are determined, and how changes in demand
and supply affect equilibrium prices and quantities.
When demand changes, both equilibrium price and quantity
change in the same direction as demand changes: increasing or
decreasing.
When supply changes, the equilibrium quantity changes in the
same direction as the supply change, but equilibrium price
changes in the opposite direction.
The table on the next slide summarizes this.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 3.5 Market Effects of Changes in
Demand or Supply
Change in Demand
or Supply
How does the equilibrium
price change?
How does the equilibrium
quantity change?
Increase in demand
Increase
Increase
Decrease in demand
Decrease
Decrease
Increase in supply
Decrease
Increase
Decrease in supply
Increase
Decrease
We can use this knowledge to predict how prices and quantities will
change in response to a demand or supply change.
We can also use this knowledge “in reverse”: if we know the price and
quantity of a product both rose or fell, we should expect a change in
demand caused the changes.
Conversely, if the price and quantity of a product moved in opposite
directions, we should infer a change in supply occurred.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 6: Why Did Drug Prices
Fall? (1 of 2)
“Do you know what’s happened to the price of drugs in the
United States? The price of cocaine, way down, the price of
marijuana, way down. You don’t have to be an expert in
economics to know that when the price goes down, it means
more stuff is coming in. That’s supply and demand.”
Ted Koppel, host of the ABC news program Nightline
Was Koppel right? That is, do falling drug prices prove the
U.S. government’s “war on drugs” was failing, and the
supply of illegal drugs was increasing
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 6: Why Did Drug Prices
Fall? (2 of 2)
There are two possible explanations:
• Koppel’s hypothesis: supply rose, resulting in lower prices
and higher quantities.
• The alternative: demand fell, resulting in lower prices and
lower quantities.
According to the U.S. Department of Justice, during this time
of falling prices, drug consumption actually decreased.
• This suggests the alternative explanation is more likely to
be correct.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Key Terms
Change in demand
Law of supply
Change in quantity demanded
Market demand curve
Change in quantity supplied
Market equilibrium
Change in supply
Market supply curve
Complements
Minimum supply price
Demand schedule
Normal good
Excess demand
Perfectly competitive market
Excess supply
Quantity demanded
Individual demand curve
Quantity supplied
Individual supply curve
Substitutes
Inferior good
Supply schedule
Law of demand
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is
provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their
courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of
any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will
destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work
and materials from it should never be made available to students
except by instructors using the accompanying text in their
classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these
restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and
the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
Chapter 4
Elasticity: A Measure of
Responsiveness
Slides in this presentation contain
hyperlinks. JAWS users should be
able to get a list of links by using
INSERT+F7
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Chapter Outline
4.1 The Price Elasticity of Demand
4.2 Using Price Elasticity
4.3 Elasticity and Total Revenue for a Linear Demand Curve
4.4 Other Elasticities of Demand
4.5 The Price Elasticity of Supply
4.6 Using Elasticities to Predict Changes in Prices
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 The Price Elasticity of Demand
List the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.
Price elasticity of demand (Ed): A measure of the
responsiveness of the quantity demanded to changes in price;
equal to the absolute value of the percentage change in quantity
demanded divided by the percentage change in price.
percentage change in quantity demanded
Ed
percentage change in price
Suppose that when the price of milk increases by 10%, the
quantity demanded of decreases by 15%:
Ed
percentage change in quantity demanded 15%
1.5
percentage change in price
10%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Computing Percentage Changes and
Elasticities
Computing elasticities requires computing percentage
changes.
We can compute percentage changes via the initial-value
method or the midpoint method.
• The initial-value method is easier.
• The midpoint method is more accurate.
In this text, we use the initial-value approach in order to
concentrate on the economic intuition rather than the math.
A comparison of calculations using the two methods is on
the next slide.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.1 Computing Price Elasticity
with Initial Values and Midpoints
Blank
Blank
Price
Quantity
Data
Initial
$20
100
Blank
New
22
80
Blank
Blank
Price
Quantity
Computation with
Initial-value method
Percentage change
$2 divided by $20, times 100 = 10%
negative 20 divided by 100, times 100 = negative 20%
Blank
Price elasticity of
demand
Blank
Blank
Computation with
midpoint method
Percentage change
Blank
Price elasticity of
demand
$2
10%
100
$20
20%
20
100
100
the absolute value of, negative 20% divided by 10%, = 2.0
20%
2.0
10%
Blank
Price
Quantity
$2 divided by $21, times 100 = 9.52%
negative 20 divided by 90, times 100 = negative 22.22%
9.52%
$2
100
$21
22.22%
9.52%
the absolute value of negative 222.22% divided by 9.52% = 2.33
2.33
22.22%
20
100
90
Blank
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Price Elasticity and the Demand Curve
Price elasticity of demand and the slope of the demand
curve are related.
percentage change in quantity demanded
Ed
percentage change in price
rise
change in price
Slope
run change in quantity
Roughly, a greater price elasticity of demand means a
shallower slope, and a smaller price elasticity of demand
means a steeper-sloped demand curve.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Elasticity and Demand
Curves (Panel A)
Elastic demand: The
price elasticity of
demand is greater than
one, so the percentage
change in quantity
exceeds the percentage
change in price.
Example goods:
restaurant meals, air
travel, movies.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Elasticity and Demand
Curves (Panel B)
Inelastic demand:
The price elasticity of
demand is less than
one, so the
percentage change in
quantity is less than
the percentage
change in price.
Example goods: milk,
salt, eggs, coffee,
cigarettes.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Elasticity and Demand
Curves (Panel C)
Unit elastic demand: The
price elasticity of demand is
one, so the percentage
change in quantity equals
the percentage change in
price.
Example goods: housing,
juice.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Elasticity and Demand
Curves (Panel D)
Perfectly inelastic
demand: The price
elasticity of demand is
zero.
In this extreme case, the
quantity demanded does
not change when the price
changes. This could only
happen if there were no
possible substitutes for the
good, say insulin for
diabetics.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.1 Elasticity and Demand
Curves (Panel E)
Perfectly elastic
demand: The price
elasticity of demand is
infinite.
In this extreme case,
buyers will buy as much
as sellers can offer at
the given price. When a
seller provides a tiny
fraction of output for the
market, this may be a
good assumption.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Elasticity and the Availability of
Substitutes
The key factor in determining the price elasticity of demand for a
particular product is the availability of substitute products.
• For diabetics, there is no substitute for insulin, so the demand
for insulin is inelastic.
• For cereal-eaters, there are many substitutes for cornflakes, so
the demand for cornflakes is elastic.
Adjustment to price changes is easier over time. So the price
elasticity of demand tends to be greater in the long run than in the
short run.
• If gasoline prices rise, you can do little about it in the short run.
• In the long run, you can move, change cars, etc.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.2 Price Elasticities of Demand
for Selected Products (1 of 2)
Blank
Inelastic
Product
Salt
Food (wealthy countries)
Weekend canoe trips
Water
Coffee
Physician visits
Sport fishing
Gasoline (short run)
Eggs
Cigarettes
Food (poor countries)
Shoes and footwear
Gasoline (long run)
Price Elasticity of
Demand
0.1
0.15
0.19
0.2
0.3
0.25
0.28
0.25
0.3
0.3
0.34
0.7
0.6
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.2 Price Elasticities of Demand
for Selected Products (2 of 2)
Blank
Unit
elastic
Elastic
Product
Housing
Fruit Juice
Automobiles
Foreign travel
Motorboats
Restaurant meals
Air travel
Movies
Specific brands of coffee
Price Elasticity of
Demand
1.0
1.0
1.2
1.8
2.2
2.3
2.4
3.7
5.6
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Other Determinants of the Price
Elasticity of Demand
1. Elasticity is higher for goods that take a relatively large part of a
consumer’s budget.
– A 10% increase in the price of gum is unlikely to change the
quantity of gum demanded by much.
– But a 10% increase in the price of cars would have a large
effect.
2. Goods that are necessities have lower elasticities of demand;
goods that are luxuries have higher elasticities of demand.
– Food demand is inelastic in both rich and poor countries.
– Demand for air travel is elastic (though for some it may be
inelastic, say for travel to a funeral).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.3 Determinants of Elasticity
Factor
Demand is relatively Demand is relatively
elastic if …
inelastic if …
Availability of
substitutes
There are many
substitutes.
There are few
substitutes.
Passage of time
a long time passes.
a short time passes.
Fraction of consumer
budget
is large.
is small.
Necessity
the product is a
luxury.
the product is a
necessity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 1: The Elasticity of Demand
for Public Transit
When the price of a city bus
or subway ride increases,
what is the price elasticity of
demand for public transit?
• In the short run (one to two
years) it is 0.40: relatively
inelastic.
• In the long run it is 0.80:
close to unit elastic.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Using Price Elasticity
Use price elasticity of demand to predict changes in quantity and
total revenue.
If we have values for two of the three variables in the elasticity formula,
we can compute the value of the third. The three variables are:
• the price elasticity of demand itself,
• percentage change in quantity, and
• the percentage change in price.
Specifically, we can rearrange the elasticity formula:
Ed
percentage change in quantity demanded
percentage change in price
percentage change in quantity demanded
percentage change in price Ed
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Predicting Changes in Quantity
Suppose you are running a campus film series, and you
know the price elasticity of demand for tickets is 2.0.
If you raise prices by 15%, how many fewer tickets will you
sell?
percentage change in quantity demanded
percentage change in price Ed
15% 2.0
30%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Price Elasticity and Total Revenue
Firms use the concept of price elasticity to predict the effects
of changing their prices.
Total revenue: The money a firm generates from selling its
product.
Suppose a firm increases the price of its product. Two things
happen:
• Good news: it gets more money for each product sold.
• Bad news: it sells fewer products.
The extent of the “bad news” depends on the price elasticity
of demand for the firm’s product.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.4 Price and Total Revenue with
Different Elasticities of Demand
Blank
Elastic Demand: Ed = 2.0
Blank
Price
Quantity Sold
Total Revenue
$10
100
$1,000
11
80
880
Blank
Inelastic Demand: Ed = 0.50
Blank
Price
Quantity Sold
Total Revenue
100
10
$1,000
120
9
1,080
When elasticity is high, the “bad news” is large, and total
revenue falls.
When elasticity is low, the “bad news” is small, and total
revenue rises.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.5 Price Elasticity and Total
Revenue
Blank
Blank
Elastic Demand: Ed > 1.0
If price …
Total
revenue …
Because the percentage change in
quantity is …
Larger than the percentage change in price.
Larger than the percentage change in price.
Blank
Blank
If price …
Total
revenue …
Smaller than the percentage change in
price.
Smaller than the percentage change in
price.
Inelastic Demand: Ed < 1.0
Because the percentage change in
quantity is …
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Elasticity to Predict the Revenue
Effects of Price Changes (1 of 2)
1. Market v s Brand Elasticity:
The demand for a specific brand of a product is more elastic
than the demand for the product.
Raising the price of all coffees would increase coffee revenue;
but raising the price of one brand would decrease revenue for
that brand.
ersu
2. Bus Fares and Deficits:
Public bus systems almost always run a deficit.
But demand is typically inelastic.
If fares were raised, the “good news” (more revenue per rider)
would dominate the “bad news” (fewer riders), so total fare
revenue would increase, potentially eliminating the deficit.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Using Elasticity to Predict the Revenue
Effects of Price Changes (2 of 2)
3. A Bumper Crop is Bad News for Farmers:
An unusually large crop of soy beans increases the number of
bushels of soy beans for sale (good news).
But the price decreases, because of the increased supply (bad
news).
But demand is inelastic, so the bad news dominates the good
news: a bumper crop results in lower overall revenues.
4. Antidrug Policies and Property Crime:
Antidrug policies raise the price of drugs. But demand for drugs
is inelastic, so total spending on drugs increases.
This increases property crime, as drug addicts commit crime to
obtain money for drugs.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 2: Vanity Plates and the
Elasticity of Demand
Virginia has the highest ratio of
vanity license plates: over 10% of
vehicles have them.
Why? Because the price is so low,
$10 per year.
If Virginia wanted to raise more
revenue from vanity license plates,
it should raise its price: the price
elasticity of demand is only 0.26.
• A 100% increase in price would
decrease quantity demanded
only 26%.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Elasticity and Total Revenue for a
Linear Demand Curve
Explain how the price elasticity of demand varies along a linear
demand curve.
It is often useful to represent the demand for a product with a linear
demand curve.
• A linear demand curve—a straight line—has a constant slope, but
that does not mean that it has a constant elasticity of demand.
In fact, the price elasticity of demand decreases as we move downward
along a linear demand curve.
• On the upper half of a linear demand curve, demand is elastic.
• On the lower half of the curve, demand is inelastic.
• At the midpoint of a linear demand curve, demand is unit elastic.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.2 Elasticity and Total Revenue
along a Linear Demand Curve (Panel A)
The slope of this demand curve is −$2 per unit quantity. We
will use this in the table on the next slide to compute the
elasticity at three points: e, u, and i (elastic, unit elastic,
and inelastic).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.6 Elasticity of Demand along a
Linear Demand Curve
A
B
C
D
E
F
Starting
Point
Change
in Price
Percentage
Change in
Price
Change
in
Quantity
Percentage
Change in
Quantity
Elasticity of
Demand
e: Elastic
‒$2
negative
$2 $2 over $80 =
negative
2.5%
2.5%
+1
negative $2 over $50 =
$2
negative
4%.
4%
+1
negative
$2 over $20 =
$2
negative
10%
10%
+1
$80
u: Unit
elastic
‒$2
i: inelastic
‒$2
10
10%
1 over125 = 4%.
25
$50
$20
1 over110 = 10%
4%
1 over 40 = 2.5%
1
2.5%
40
absolute value of 10% over
negative 2.5% = 4.
10%
4
2.5%
absolute value of 4% over
negative 4% = 1.
4%
1
4%
absolute2.5%
value of 2.5% over
negative 10% = 0.25
0.25
10%
The slope of −$2 per unit quantity means each increase in quantity of 1
(column D) is associated with the price decreasing by $2 (column B).
The elasticity is lower at greater quantities (lower prices): a large
percentage change in price induces a smaller quantity change.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.2 Elasticity and Total Revenue along
a Linear Demand Curve (Both Panels)
Since elasticity varies along the
linear demand curve, so does
the total revenue:
• When demand is elastic,
lowering price raises total
revenue.
• When demand is inelastic,
raising price raises total
revenue.
• When demand is unit elastic,
total revenue is maximized.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 3: Drones and the Lower
Half of a Linear Demand Curve
Suppose a firm that produces hobby
drones (for civilian use) has a linear
demand curve for its product, with a
vertical intercept of $800. The firm
currently charges a price of $300.
Should the firm raise its price? Yes!
1. The price is below the midpoint of
the linear demand curve, so
raising price would increase
revenue.
2. It would need to make fewer
drones, so its costs would fall.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.4 Other Elasticities of Demand
Define the income elasticity and cross-price elasticity
of demand.
Price elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of
consumers to changes in the price of a particular good.
But demand depends on other variables too; we can obtain
an elasticity for those variables, by seeing how quantity
demanded responds to changes in those other variables.
We will examine the effects of income and the prices of
related goods.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Income Elasticity of Demand
Income elasticity of demand: A measure of the responsiveness
of demand to changes in consumer income; equal to the
percentage change in the quantity demanded divided by the
percentage change in income.
percentage change in quantity demanded
Ei
percentage change in income
If a 10% increase in income increases the quantity of books
demanded by 15%:
percentage change in quantity demanded 15%
Ei
1.5
percentage change in income
10%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
Cross-price elasticity of demand: A measure of the
responsiveness of demand to changes in the price of another
good; equal to the percentage change in the quantity demanded
of one good (X) divided by the percentage change in the price of
another good (Y).
percentage change in quantity of X demanded
E xy
percentage change in price of Y
If a 20% increase in the price of bananas (B) increases the
quantity of apples (A) demanded by 5%:
E AB
percentage change in quantity of A demanded 5%
0.25
percentage change in price of B
20%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 4.7 Income and Cross-Price
Elasticities for Different Types of Goods
This elasticity
Is Positive for …
Is Negative for …
Income elasticity
Normal goods
Inferior goods
Cross-price elasticity
Substitute goods
Complementary goods
Recall inferior goods are ones we buy less of as our income
rises, resulting in a negative income elasticity of demand.
• Normal goods—ones we buy more of as our income rises—
have a positive income elasticity of demand.
Substitutes are bought in place of one another: when the price of
one rises, the demand for the other increases (a positive crossprice elasticity).
• Complements work the other way: when the price of one rises,
we buy less of the other—a negative cross-price elasticity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
How Are These Elasticities Useful?
During a recession, incomes fall (or rise slowly).
• If you operate a retail store and know the income elasticity of
demand for your product and how incomes are changing, you
can predict how sales of your product will change.
A supermarket sells many products. When ordering for the
produce department of a supermarket, suppose you know
bananas will be on sale.
• If you know the price change for the bananas, and the crossprice elasticities for other products, you can predict how much
more or less you will sell of the other products, and order
accordingly.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 4: I Can Find That
Elasticity in Four Clicks!
The USDA has a web site
that provides estimates of
demand elasticities (ownprice, income, or crossprice) for hundreds of food
products, and for dozens of
countries.
Check it out:
https://data.ers.usda.gov/
reports.aspx?ID=17825
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.5 The Price Elasticity of Supply
List the determinants of the price elasticity of supply.
We can also use elasticity do measure the responsiveness
of firms to changes in prices.
Price elasticity of supply: A measure of the
responsiveness of the quantity supplied to changes in price;
equal to the percentage change in quantity supplied divided
by the percentage change in price.
Es
percentage change in quantity supplied
percentage change in price
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.3 The Slope of the Supply
Curve and Supply Elasticity
As with demand curves, a steeper slope means a smaller price
elasticity of supply, and a shallower slope means a greater price
elasticity of supply. For panel A,
percentage change in quantity supplied 2%
Es
0.10
percentage change in price
20%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
What Determines the Price Elasticity of
Supply?
The price elasticity of supply is determined by how rapidly
production costs increase as the total output of the industry
increases.
• If the marginal cost increases rapidly, the supply curve is
relatively steep and the price elasticity is relatively low.
• Consider the pencil industry: increasing output is unlikely
to increase input costs much, so the supply curve will be
quite flat, with a high price elasticity of supply.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Role of Time: Short-Run versus
Long-Run Supply Elasticity
The supply curve is positively sloped because of two
increases to an increase in price:
• Short run: A higher price encourages existing firms to
increase their output by purchasing more materials and
hiring more workers.
• Long run: New firms enter the market and existing firms
expand their production facilities to produce more output.
Greater quantity changes will result from a given price
change in the long run: a greater price elasticity of supply.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Extreme Cases: Perfectly Inelastic
Supply and Perfectly Elastic Supply
For some goods and services, there is only a fixed amount of the
good or service available: a perfectly inelastic supply.
Perfectly inelastic supply: The price elasticity of supply equals
zero.
Land is a good example: as Will Rogers said, “The trouble with land
is that they’re not making it anymore.”
For other goods and services, the marginal cost of production may
not change as we provide one more unit. These have a perfectly
elastic supply.
Perfectly elastic supply: The price elasticity of supply is equal to
infinity.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.4 Perfectly Inelastic Supply
and Perfectly Elastic Supply
In Panel A, the quantity supplied is the same at every price, so the
price elasticity of supply is zero.
In Panel B, the quantity supplied is infinitely responsive to changes
in price, so the price elasticity of supply is infinite.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Predicting Changes in Quantity
Supplied
We can rearrange the formula for price elasticity of supply as we
did for price elasticity of demand:
Es
percentage change in quantity supplied
percentage change in price
percentage change in quantity supplied
percentage change in price Es
If the elasticity of supply is 0.80 and price rises by 5%:
percentage change in quantity supplied
percentage change in price Es 5% 0.80 4%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 5: The Short-Run and LongRun Elasticity of Supply of Coffee
Suppose the price of coffee beans
rises.
In the short run, farmers will use
more fertilizer and water, and more
labor, to obtain greater output per
bush.
In the long run, they will also plant
more bushes, resulting in a greater
output increase for the same size
price increase—greater price
elasticity of supply in the long run.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.6 Using Elasticities to Predict
Changes in Prices
Use demand and supply elasticities to predict changes
in equilibrium prices.
When demand or supply changes, we can use a simple
demand-and-supply graph to predict whether the equilibrium
price will increase or decrease.
But we might want to do better: predicting how much the
equilibrium price will change.
• Demand and supply elasticities can help us to make this
prediction.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Price Effects of a Change in
Demand
Suppose the demand for milk increases. Immediately, there
is an excess demand for milk. We know the price will rise to
eliminate the excess demand.
What would make the resulting increase in price relatively
small?
1. A small increase in demand (so the amount of excess
demand is small).
2. Highly elastic demand (so the quantity demanded
changes a lot in response to a price change).
3. Highly elastic supply (so the quantity supplied changes a
lot in response to a price change).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.5 An Increase in Demand
Increases the Equilibrium Price
Demand increases by 35 million
gallons; perhaps a new trade
deal sends 35 million gallons
overseas.
The supply elasticity is 2.5 and
the demand elasticity is 1.0.
A 10% increase in price will
increase quantity supplied by
25% (25 million) and decrease
quantity demanded by 10% (10
million), eliminating the excess
demand.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Predicting the Change In Equilibrium
Price
More generally, we can use the following formula:
percentage change in equilibrium price
percentage change in demand
Es Ed
In our example:
percentage change in equilibrium price
35%
2.5 1.0
35%
3.5
10%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
The Price Effects of a Change in Supply
Let’s work through a similar exercise for a change in supply.
Suppose the supply of shoes decreases. Immediately, there is an
excess demand for shoes. We know the price will rise to eliminate
the excess demand.
What would make the resulting increase in price relatively small?
1. A small decrease in supply (so the amount of excess demand is
small).
2. Highly elastic demand (so the quantity demanded changes a lot
in response to a price change).
3. Highly elastic supply (so the quantity supplied changes a lot in
response to a price change).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 4.6 An Increase in Demand
Increases the Equilibrium Price
The supply of shoes falls by 30
million pairs; perhaps a
protectionist government
introduces import restrictions.
The supply elasticity is 2.3 and
the demand elasticity is 0.7.
A 10% increase in price will
increase quantity supplied by
23% (23 million) and decrease
quantity demanded by 7% (7
million), eliminating the excess
demand.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Finding the Change In Equilibrium Price
More generally, we can use the following formula:
percentage change in equilibrium price
percentage change in supply
Es Ed
In our example:
30%
percentage change in equilibrium price
2.3 0.7
30%
3.0
10%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 6: A Broken Pipeline and
the Price of Gasoline (1 of 2)
In 2003, a pipeline break
decreased the supply of
gasoline to the city of Phoenix
by 30%.
The equilibrium price
increased only 40%; with a
short-run demand elasticity of
demand for gasoline of 0.2, a
price increase of 150% would
have been necessary to
eliminate the excess demand
if there were not supply
adjustment.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 6: A Broken Pipeline and
the Price of Gasoline (2 of 2)
What actually happened? Gasoline was diverted to Phoenix via a
different pipeline: quantity supplied increased in response to the high
prices.
Suppose the price elasticity of supply was 0.55:
percentage change in equilibrium price
percentage change in supply
Es Ed
30%
0.55 0.20
30%
0.75
40%
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Key Terms
Cross-price elasticity of demand
Perfectly inelastic demand
Elastic demand
Perfectly inelastic supply
Income elasticity of demand
Price elasticity of demand (Ed)
Inelastic demand
Price elasticity of supply
Perfectly elastic demand
Total revenue
Perfectly elastic supply
Unit elastic demand
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright
This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is
provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their
courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of
any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will
destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work
and materials from it should never be made available to students
except by instructors using the accompanying text in their
classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these
restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and
the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Survey of Economics: Principles,
Applications and Tools
Eighth Edition
Chapter 5
Production Technology
and Cost
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Chapter Outline
5.1 Economic Cost and Economic Profit
5.2 A Firm with a Fixed Production Facility: Short-Run Costs
5.3 Production and Cost in the Long Run
5.4 Examples of Production Cost
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
5.1 Economic Cost and Economic Profit
Define economic cost and economic profit.
A firm’s objective is to maximize its economic profit:
economic profit total revenue economic cost
Economic profit: Total revenue minus economic cost.
Economic cost: The opportunity cost of the inputs used in the
production process; equal to explicit cost plus implicit cost.
The economic cost is the entire opportunity cost of production:
whatever must be sacrificed in the course of production.
Explicit cost: A monetary payment.
Implicit cost: An opportunity cost that does not involve a
monetary payment.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.1 Economic Cost versus
Accounting Cost
blank
Economic Cost
Explicit: monetary payments for labour,
capital, materials
$10,000
Accounting
Cost
$10,000
Implicit: opportunity cost of
entrepreneur’s time
5,000
-
Implicit: opportunity cost of funds
2,000
-
Total
17,000
10,000
Accountants calculate profit and cost differently from economists. Their
purpose is to account for flows of money. Economists are interested in
questions like “should this firm continue to operate?” which require
considering implicit costs as well as flows of money.
Accounting cost: The explicit costs of production.
Accounting profit: Total revenue minus accounting cost.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 1: Opportunity Cost and
Entrepreneurship
A homeowner is considering
renting out his or her home
through Airbnb, earning $90 for a
typical two-night stay.
While that may sound like a nice
payoff, it fails to account for the
opportunity cost of the
homeowner’s time:
• Emails to arrange the stay
• Cleaning up after guests leave
The economic profit will be much less than $90.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
5.2 A Firm with a Fixed Production
Facility: Short-Run Costs
Draw the short-run marginal-cost and average-cost
curves.
Consider first the case of a firm with a fixed production
facility.
Suppose you have decided to start a small firm to produce
plastic paddles for rafts.
Before we can discuss the cost of production, we need
information about the nature of the production process.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.1 Total-Product Curve (1 of 2)
Total-product curve: A
curve showing the
relationship between the
quantity of labor and the
quantity of output produced,
ceteris paribus.
For the first two workers,
output increases at an
increasing rate because of
labor specialization.
Marginal product of labor:
The change in output from
one additional unit of labor.
Labor
Quantity of
Output Produced
Marginal
Product of
Labor
1
1
1
2
5
4
3
8
3
4
10
2
5
11
1
6
11.5
0.5
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.1 Total-Product Curve (2 of 2)
Diminishing returns
occurs for three or more
workers, so output
increases at a decreasing
rate.
Diminishing returns: As
one input increases while
the other inputs are held
fixed, output increases at
a decreasing rate.
Labor
Quantity of
Output Produced
Marginal
Product of
Labor
1
1
1
2
5
4
3
8
3
4
10
2
5
11
1
6
11.5
0.5
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Short-Run Total Cost
In the short-run analysis of costs, we divide production costs
into two types, fixed cost and variable cost.
Fixed cost (FC): Cost that does not vary with the quantity
produced.
Variable cost (VC): Cost that varies with the quantity
produced.
Short-run total cost (TC): The total cost of production when
at least one input is fixed; equal to fixed cost plus variable
cost.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.2 Short-Run Costs: Fixed Cost,
Variable Cost, and Total Cost
The short-run total-cost curve shows the relationship between the
quantity of output and production costs, given a fixed production
facility.
Short-run total cost equals fixed cost (the cost that does not vary
with the quantity produced) plus variable cost (the cost that varies
with the quantity produced).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.2 Short-Run Costs (1 of 2)
1
Labor
2
Output
3
Fixed
Cost
(FC)
4
Variable
Cost (V
C)
5
Total
Cost (TC)
6
Average
Fixed
Cost (AF
C)
7
Average
Variable
Cost (AV
C)
8
Average
Total
Cost (AT
C)
9
Marginal
Cost (M
C)
0
0
$100
$0
$100
-
-
-
-
1
1
100
50
150
$100.00
$50.00
$150.00
$50.00
2
5
100
100
200
20.00
20.00
40.00
12.50
3
8
100
150
250
12.50
18.75
31.25
16.67
4
10
100
200
300
10.00
20.00
30.00
25.00
5
11
100
250
350
9.09
22.73
31.82
50.00
6
11.5
100
300
400
8.70
26.09
34.78
100.00
The table shows a variety of measures of cost for the firm.
Average fixed cost (AFC): Fixed cost divided by the quantity produced.
Average variable cost (AVC): Variable cost divided by the quantity
produced.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.2 Short-Run Costs (2 of 2)
1
Labor
2
Output
3
Fixed
Cost
(FC)
4
Variable
Cost (V
C)
5
Total
Cost (TC)
6
Average
Fixed
Cost (AF
C)
7
Average
Variable
Cost (AV
C)
8
Average
Total
Cost (AT
C)
9
Marginal
Cost (M
C)
0
0
$100
$0
$100
-
-
-
-
1
1
100
50
150
$100.00
$50.00
$150.00
$50.00
2
5
100
100
200
20.00
20.00
40.00
12.50
3
8
100
150
250
12.50
18.75
31.25
16.67
4
10
100
200
300
10.00
20.00
30.00
25.00
5
11
100
250
350
9.09
22.73
31.82
50.00
6
11.5
100
300
400
8.70
26.09
34.78
100.00
Short-run average total cost (ATC): Short-run total cost divided by
the quantity produced; equal to AFC plus AVC.
ATC
TC FC VC
AFC AVC
Q
Q
Q
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.3 Short-Run Average Costs
The short-run average-total-cost
curve (ATC) is U-shaped.
• As the quantity increases, fixed
costs are spread over more
units, pushing down the ATC.
• As the quantity increases,
diminishing returns eventually
pull up the ATC.
The gap between ATC and AVC is
the average fixed cost (AFC).
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Short-Run Marginal Cost
Short-run marginal cost (MC): The change in short-run
total cost resulting from a one-unit increase in output.
TC
change in TC
MC
Q
change in output
One worker produces 1 paddle, with total cost $150.
Two workers produce 5 paddles, with total cost $200.
TC $200 $150 $50
MC
$12.50
Q
5 1
4
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.4 Short-Run Marginal and
Average Cost
The marginal-cost curve (MC) is
negatively sloped for small
quantities of output, because of
the benefits of labor
specialization, and positively
sloped for large quantities,
because of diminishing returns.
The MC curve intersects the
average-cost curve (ATC) at the
minimum point of the average
curve.
At this point ATC is neither
falling nor rising.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.3 Marginal Grade and Average
Grade
Labor
Marginal
Grade
Number of
Courses
Grade
Points
Grade Point Average
Starting point
-
9
27
3.0 = 27 over 9
Marginal grade < GPA
D
10
28 = 27+1
2.8 = 28 over 10
Marginal grade = GPA
B
10
30 = 27+3
3.0 = 30 over 10
Marginal grade > GPA
A
10
31 = 27+4
3.0 27 / 9
2.8 28 / 10
3.0 30 / 10
3.1
= 31
3.1
over
31/1010
To illustrate the relationship between marginal and average, suppose
you have a B (3.0) average after 9 classes, and are waiting for the
grade for the 10th to come in.
The 10th is your marginal grade; your GPA is your average grade.
• If the 10th grade is less than your GPA, your GPA will fall.
• If it is equal to your GPA, your GPA will stay the same.
• If it is greater than your GPA, your GPA will rise.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 2: The Rising Marginal
Cost of Crude Oil
The first 40 million barrels of oil
produced worldwide per day
have a marginal cost less than
$10 per barrel; oil costs little to
extract in the Middle East and
Russia.
The next 25 million barrels cost
about $20 per barrel, from more
expensive offshore rigs and oil
sands projects.
Higher quantities see the
marginal cost rise quickly, for
Arctic drilling, biodiesel, etc.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
5.3 Production and Cost in the Long
Run
Draw the long-run marginal-cost and average cost curves.
The long run is defined as the period of time over which a firm is
perfectly flexible in its choice of all inputs.
• In the long run, a firm can build or modify a production facility
such as a factory, store, office, or restaurant.
The key difference between the short run and the long run is that
there are no diminishing returns in the long run.
• Diminishing returns occur because workers share a fixed
production facility.
• In the long run, a firm can expand its production facility as its
workforce grows.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Expansion and Replication
Suppose our paddle-production firm was producing 10 paddles
per day, with a total cost of $300 per day—an average cost of
$30 per paddle.
If we wanted to double production, we could do so in our old
facility; but the workers would be cramped, and average costs
would rise.
Another option: build another identical workshop, to replicated
our already successful production methods.
The cost to produce, when we can flexibly change our facilities,
is the long-run total cost.
Long-run total cost (LTC): The total cost of production when a
firm is perfectly flexible in choosing its inputs.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.5 Expansion and
Replication (1 of 2)
Initially (up to point b) the short-run
and long-run total cost curves are the
same; while average costs are falling,
replication is not useful.
Long-run average cost (LAC): The
long-run cost divided by the quantity
produced.
Labor
1 Capital
2 Output
3 Labor
Cost
4 Long-Run Total
Cost (LTC)
5 Long-Run Average
Cost (LAC)
1
$100
1
$ 50
$150
$150
2
100
5
100
200
40
4
100
10
200
300
30
8
200
20
400
600
30
12
300
30
600
900
30
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.5 Expansion and
Replication (2 of 2)
Once we exhaust our gains from
specialization, we can replicate and
achieve constant returns to scale.
Constant returns to scale: A
situation in which the long-run total
cost increases proportionately with
output, so average cost is constant.
Labor
1 Capital
2 Output
3 Labor
Cost
4 Long-Run Total
Cost (LTC)
5 Long-Run Average
Cost (LAC)
1
$100
1
$ 50
$150
$150
2
100
5
100
200
40
4
100
10
200
300
30
8
200
20
400
600
30
12
300
30
600
900
30
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Long-Run Marginal Cost
If we achieve constant returns to scale by replication, each
additional batch of output costs the same as the ones
before, so the long-run marginal cost is constant also.
Long-run marginal cost (LMC): The change in long-run
cost resulting from a one-unit increase in output.
We may be able to do even better—say, by combining two
workshops into a single larger workshop. Then the long-run
marginal cost would be falling.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Reducing Output with Indivisible Inputs
While replication will often allow us to increase production and keep
average costs the same, we often cannot decrease production with the
same result.
Many inputs cannot be divided—they must be all-or-nothing.
Indivisible input: An input that cannot be scaled down to produce a
smaller quantity of output.
• For example, to produce up to 10 paddles per day, perhaps we need
one plastic mold; we cannot have half a mold.
• Similarly, a hospital cannot buy half an MRI machine, and a railroad
company can’t build half a set of tracks.
• This helps to explain why long-run average costs are often high for
small quantities.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Scaling Down and Labor Specialization
Another problem with getting smaller is that we cannot
benefit as much from labor specialization.
• In our paddle-production example, if we cut down to just
a couple of workers, each would have to perform many
tasks. With more workers, they could specialize.
• Similarly a large hospital benefits from size by having
specialist surgeons, radiologists, etc. A small hospital
could have one person perform multiple roles, but they
would likely not be as productive; or it could contract
some roles out, at higher cost.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Economies of Scale
The foregoing examples help to explain why larger firms can
enjoy economies of scale.
Economies of scale: A situation in which the long-run
average cost of production decreases as output increases.
Eventually we will likely exhaust all possible economies of
scale.
Minimum efficient scale: The output at which scale
economies are exhausted.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Diseconomies of Scale
Could a firm get so big, its average cost actually starts to rise?
Diseconomies of scale: A situation in which the long-run average
cost of production increases as output increases.
Diseconomies of scale could occur because of:
• Coordination problems: Organizing a large operation with many
layers of management may be difficult to do effectively.
• Increasing input costs: A firm could get so big that it may be
forced to pay higher prices for its inputs. For example, a large
coal-fired power plant may have to source coal from far away,
with higher delivery costs than a small power plant would face.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.6 Actual Long-Run Cost Curves for
Aluminum, Truck Freight, and Hospital Services
Different industries can
have dramatically different
long-run average cost
curves.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Short-Run Versus Long-Run Average
Cost
Why is the firm’s short-run average-cost curve U-shaped,
while the long-run average-cost curve is L-shaped?
• The difference between the short run and long run is a
firm’s flexibility in choosing inputs.
In the long run, a firm can increase all of its inputs, scaling up
its operation by building a larger production facility.
• As a result, the firm will not suffer from diminishing returns.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Application 3: Indivisible Inputs and
the Cost of Fake Killer Whales
Sea lions off the Washington coast
threaten some fish species with
extinction and threaten commercial
fisheries.
One innovative idea: build big
plastic killer whales, on rollercoaster-like rails, to scare off the
sea lions.
The cost for the first fake whale
would be $16,000: $11,000 for the
plastic mold, and $5,000 for labor
and materials; each extra whale
would cost only $5,000.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
5.4 Examples of Production Cost
Provide examples of production costs.
In this section we will look at actual production costs for
several products:
• Electricity from wind turbines
• Music videos
• Solar and nuclear power
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.4 Wind Turbines and the
Average Cost of Electricity
blank
Small Turbine
(150 kilowatt)
Large Turbine
(600 kilowatt)
Purchase price of turbine
$150,000
$420,000
Installation cost
$100,000
$100,000
Operating and maintenance cost
$75,000
$126,000
Total Cost
$325,000
$646,000
Electricity generated (kilowatt-hours)
5 million
20 million
Average cost (per kilowatt-hour)
$0.065
$0.032
A large wind turbine is more expensive, but also more cost-effective:
installation and maintenance costs are relatively low for the large turbine,
considering the much higher output of electricity.
A wind turbine company would experience economies of scale as it moved
from small to large turbines.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Figure 5.7 Average-Cost Curve for an
Information Good
A music video is an
information good; almost
all of its cost is in the initial
production, and the
marginal cost of
reproduction is essentially
zero.
The average cost will fall
for all reasonable
quantities.
A similar cost structure
exists for other products
distributed online.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Solar Versus Nuclear: The Crossover
In 1998, the cost of electricity produced with solar technology
was $0.32 per kilowatt-hour (Kwh), vs $0.07 per Kwh for
nuclear.
Over the last 20 years, the cost for electricity from nuclear
power plants has increased to about $0.16 per Kwh, because
the cost of building reactors has increased
Meanwhile the cost from solar has decreased: $0.21 per Kwh
in 2005, and $0.16 per Kwh in 2010.
As further innovations happen in the solar industry, it is likely
that solar energy costs will continue to fall: solar has crossed
over to being more cost-effective than nuclear.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.5 The Language and
Mathematics of Costs (1 of 3)
Type of Cost
Definition
Symbols and
Equations
Economic cost
The opportunity cost of the inputs used
in the production process; equal to
explicit cost plus implicit cost
-
Explicit cost
The actual monetary payment for inputs
-
Implicit cost
The opportunity cost of inputs that do not
involve a monetary payment
-
Accounting cost
Explicit cost
-
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Table 5.5 The Language and
Mathematics of Costs (2 of 3)
Type of Cost
Definition
Symbols and
Equations
Short-Run Costs
blank
blank
Fixed cost
Cost that does not vary with the quantity
produced
FC
Variable cost
Cost that varies with the qu...
Purchase answer to see full
attachment